The
salary of the chief executive of a large corporation is not a market award
for achievement. It is frequently in the nature of a warm personal gesture
by the individual to himself.
John Kenneth Galbraith ---
Click Here
If you aren’t
(cynical) now, you will by the time you finish the new Bebchuk and Fried
paper on executive compensation. They
paint a fairly gloomy picture of managers exerting their power to “extract
rents and to camouflage the extent of their rent extraction.”
Rather than designed to solve agency cost problems, the paper makes the
case that executive pay can by an agency cost in and of itself.
Let’s hope things aren’t this bad.
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=364220
They
say that patriotism is the last refuge
To which a scoundrel clings.
Steal a little and they throw you in jail,
Steal a lot and they make you king.
There's only one step down from here, baby,
It's called the land of permanent bliss.
What's a sweetheart like you doin' in a dump like this?
Lyrics of a Bob Dylan song forwarded by Damian Gadal [DGADAL@CI.SANTA-BARBARA.CA.US]
Bankers bet with their bank's capital, not
their own. If the bet goes right, they get a huge bonus; if it misfires,
that's the shareholders' problem.
Sebastian Mallaby. Council on Foreign Relations, as
quoted by Avital Louria Hahn, "Missing: How Poor Risk-Management
Techniques Contributed to the Subprime Mess," CFO Magazine, March
2008, Page 53 ---
http://www.cfo.com/article.cfm/10755469/c_10788146?f=magazine_featured
Now that the Fed is going to bail out these crooks with taxpayer funds
makes it all the worse.
Bob Jensen's "Rotten to the Core" threads are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm
That some bankers have ended up in
prison is not a matter of scandal, but what is outrageous is the fact that all
the others are free.
Honoré
de Balzac
I’d been working for the bank for about five
weeks when I woke up on the balcony of a ski resort in the Swiss Alps. It
was midnight and I was drunk. One of my fellow management trainees was
urinating onto the skylight of the lobby below us; another was hurling wine
glasses into the courtyard. Behind us, someone had stolen the hotel’s
shoe-polishing machine and carried it into the room; there were a line of
drunken bankers waiting to use it. Half of them were dripping wet, having
gone swimming in all their clothes and been too drunk to remember to take
them off. It took several more weeks of this before the bank considered us
properly trained. . . . By the time I arrived on Wall Street in 1999, the
link between derivatives and the real world had broken down. Instead of
being used to reduce risk, 95 per cent of their use was speculation - a
polite term for gambling. And leveraging - which means taking a large amount
of risk for a small amount of money. So while derivatives, and the financial
industry more broadly, had started out serving industry, by the late 1990s
the situation had reversed. The Market had become a near-religious force in
our culture; industry, society, and politicians all bowed down to it. It was
pretty clear what The Market didn’t like. It didn’t like being closely
watched. It didn’t like rules that governed its behaviour. It didn’t like
goods produced in First-World countries or workers who made high wages, with
the notable exception of financial sector employees. This last point
bothered me especially.
Philipp Meyer,
American Rust (Simon & Schuster, 2009) ---
http://search.barnesandnoble.com/American-Rust/Philipp-Meyer/e/9780385527514/?itm=1
American excess: A Wall Street trader tells all - Americas, World - The
Independent
http://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/americas/american-excess--a-wall-street-trader-tells-all-1674614.html
Jensen Comment
This book reads pretty much like an update on the derivatives scandals
featured by Frank Partnoy covering the Roaring 1990s before the dot.com
scandals broke. There were of course other insiders writing about these
scandals as well ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm#DerivativesFrauds
It would seem that bankers and investment bankers do not learn from their
own mistake. The main cause of the scandals is always pay for performance
schemes run amuck.
The End of Investment Banking ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/2008Bailout.htm#InvestmentBanking
Perks, Payouts, and Pricey
Breakups (think golden parachutes) : Takeaways From 2019’s Public-College
Presidential-Pay Survey ---
https://www.chronicle.com/interactives/what-presidents-make?utm_source=at&utm_medium=en&utm_source=Iterable&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=campaign_1366850&cid=at&source=ams&sourceId=296279
Jensen Comment
Except for the golden parachutes I'm all for high salaries and perks that
are tied to increased funds that are pegged to exceptional efforts to raise
additional funds. The left complains about enormous salaries and perks of
CEOs in the private sector. Although I think that some of these in the
private sector are outrageous (such as Elon Musk's $56 billion new salary
from Tesla). I'm not opposed to very high salaries that can be attributed to
efforts of executives.
The problem is
differentiating "success" to the performance of the CEO versus events that
would have led to "success" under most any CEO. For example, a $100 million
gift to a college may have come about from efforts of former CEOs --- a gift
that just happened to come to fruition later on. And there could be other
reasons for the gift. The 2020 $100 million gift to the University of
Arkansas that follows other huge gifts from the Walton Foundation is
probably more a function of location of flagship University of Arkansas
since Sam Walton commenced Walmarts and Sam's Clubs in Bentonville, Arkansas
that continues to be the home base of this trillion-dollar company.
The success of Microsoft
under CEO Steve Ballmer is probably due more to the prior efforts of Bill
Gates. However, the recent
remarkable success of Microsoft is probably due more to the efforts of CEO
Satya Nadella than to prior CEOs Bill Gates and Steve Ballmer.
Nadella transformed the company form a decadent system of fiefdoms
into a hugely successful system of collaborators. ---
https://www.forbes.com/sites/grantfreeland/2019/03/18/microsoft-ceo-satya-nadellas-success-secret/#255dbe2f67ef
Nadella earns every penny of his salary and perks.
And the Bill Gates and the
Gates Foundation benefited from the billions of dollars increase in the
value of Microsoft common stock under Satya Nadella.
As I said enormous CEO
salaries are sometimes justified and sometimes not justified. The trick is
not overpaying the CEO's who did not really earn those huge salaries and
perks.
Harvard: CEO Pay is Even More
Outrageous Than It Seems
https://hbr.org/video/5728073095001/ceo-pay-is-even-more-outrageous-than-it-seems
From the CFO Journal's Morning Ledger on June
29, 2018
Good
morning. Large U.S. companies are increasingly putting caps on director
pay, but at levels that are often significantly above existing
compensation levels,
reports the WSJ's Theo Francis.
About half of the 100 largest U.S. firms have limited pay to between
$500,000 and $1 million, according to a new study by pay consultancy
Compensation Advisory Partners. Most set limits at least triple what
they currently pay in equity grants, CAP found.
Median pay for non-management directors rose 3.4% to $300,000 or more
last year, up from $290,000 in 2016, according to the study. Median
director pay for a similar group of companies was $257,000 in 2012 and
$225,000 in 2008.
The change comes in response to challenges from shareholders, said Dan
Laddin, founding partner of CAP. “The view was that directors had paid
themselves too much, and because directors get to decide their own pay,
there’s an inherent conflict of interest.”
"The Pay-for-Performance Myth,"
By Eric Chemi and Ariana Giorgi, Bloomberg Businessweek, July 22,
2014 ---
http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2014-07-22/for-ceos-correlation-between-pay-and-stock-performance-is-pretty-random?campaign_id=DN072214
Aside from outrageous compensation
levels of top executives, my biggest gripe is how executives are paid
outrageous salaries and golden parachutes even when they fail
Jensen Note
This could be made into a good accounting teaching case on how to account for
all of this.
"Investors Get Stung Twice by Executives’ Lavish Pay Packages," by
Grechen Morgenson, The New York Times, July 8, 2016 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2016/07/10/business/investors-get-stung-twice-by-executives-lavish-pay-packages.html?_r=0
. . .
When compared with those companies’ earnings or
revenue, $20 million may not sound like much. But looking at pay another
way, said David J. Winters, chief executive at Wintergreen Advisers, a
money management firm in Mountain Lakes, N.J., brings a clearer picture
of the costs that these lush packages mean for shareholders.
The analysis suggested by Mr. Winters focuses
on the stock awards given to top corporate executives every year, and
the two kinds of costs they impose on shareholders. Stock grants are a
substantial piece of the pay puzzle: Last year, they accounted for $8.7
million of the $20 million median C.E.O. package, according to Equilar,
a compensation analysis firm in Redwood City, Calif.
Cost No. 1 is the dilution for existing
shareholders that results from these grants. As a company issues shares,
it reduces the value of existing stockholders’ stakes.
A second cost to consider, Mr. Winters said, is
the money companies pay to repurchase their shares in trying to offset
that dilutive effect on other stockholders’ stakes.
“We realized that dilution was systemic in the
Standard & Poor’s 500,” Mr. Winters said in an interview, “and that
buybacks were being used not necessarily to benefit the shareholder but
to offset the dilution from executive compensation. We call it a
look-through cost that companies charge to their shareholders. It is an
expense that is effectively hidden.”
Mr. Winters and his colleague Liz Cohernour,
Wintergreen’s chief operating officer, totaled the compensation stock
grants dispensed by S.&P. 500 companies and added to those figures the
share repurchases made by the companies to reduce the dilution
associated with the grants.
What they found: The average annual dilution
among S.&P. 500 companies relating to executive pay was 2.5 percent of a
company’s shares outstanding. Meanwhile, the costs of buying back shares
to reduce that dilution equaled an average 1.6 percent of the
outstanding shares. Added together, the shareholder costs of executive
pay in the S.&P. 500 represented 4.1 percent of each company’s shares
outstanding.
Of course, these numbers are far greater at
certain companies. The 15 companies with the highest combination of
dilution and buybacks had an average of 10.2 percent of their shares
outstanding.
“It’s not only today’s expense,” Mr. Winters
said. “It’s that the costs of dilution over time have been going up, so
you have a snowballing effect.”
FIFA World Cup Soccer ---
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/FIFA_World_Cup
Bloomberg, June 3, 2016
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-06-03/fifa-top-three-bosses-netted-80-million-in-pay-and-severance?cmpid=BBD060316_BIZ&utm_medium=email&utm_source=newsletter&utm_campaign=
FIFA’s Top Three Bosses Netted $80 Million in
Pay and Severance
Disgraced ex-president Sepp Blatter, former
Secretary-General Jerome Valcke and former CFO Markus Kattner shared
more than $80 million over the past five years in bonuses, incentives
and salary increases that they signed off on themselves, according to
soccer’s global governing body. All three men had already been suspended
or fired by FIFA. In a separate statement, the Swiss authorities said
they raided FIFA’s offices a day ago.
Bob Jensen's
Fraud Updates
---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudUpdates.htm
Outrageous CEO Perks
From 24/7 Wall Street on December 11, 2013
CEO compensation, relative to the amount the
average american is paid, has skyrocketed in the past few decades. In
1965, the average CEO pay was 18.3 times the average worker pay. By
2012, CEOs made 200 times workers pay. In addition to huge paychecks,
the nation’s biggest corporate heads are also often receiving special
treatment and perks that arguably cross the line of fair compensation
for work performed. But that's frequently just the beginning.
Here are eight outrageous CEO perks.
The total return of the S&P 500 index fell by nearly 40% last year, the
second-worst performance by America’s stockmarket since 1825 ---
http://www.simoleonsense.com/us-stockmarket-returns-since-1825/
But Wall Street's pay packages in 2009 are shooting for all time highs ---
Click Here
"Compensation and the Myth of the Corporate Superstar," by Charles
M. Elson and Craig K. Ferrere, Harvard Business Review Blog, February
1, 2012 ---
Click Here
http://blogs.hbr.org/cs/2012/02/compensation_and_the_myth_of_t.html?referral=00563&cm_mmc=email-_-newsletter-_-daily_alert-_-alert_date&utm_source=newsletter_daily_alert&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=alert_date
The public is up in arms about some of the big
bonuses being paid to the CEOs of big bailed-out banks.
The boss of Britain's RBS, one of the biggest casualties of the banking
crash, has felt obliged to turn down a $1.5 million bonus in the face of
mounting anger and the threat of legislation.
It all used to be very different.
Al Dunlap, the former Sunbeam CEO, and once
handsomely rewarded corporate icon, was fond of reminding his investors
that "the best bargain is an expensive CEO." Great managers, the
argument went, deserve the big bucks because of the tremendous wealth
they create.
According to this logic, expecting RBS to pay its CEO, Stephen Hester,
less is analogous to asking that it pay less for any other necessary
business commodity. If executive talent has a price, a firm will get
only that which it pays for. So if Stephen Hester were not paid his
bonus, another firm would bid away his services and RBS would not be
able to attract and retain similar talent at more modest pay levels.
This notion that there is an open and
competitive market for highly talented executives is at the heart of the
process by which CEO pay is set. Board compensation committees rely
almost exclusively on comparisons to CEO compensation at companies of
similar size and in similar industries.
This practice, known as peer benchmarking, is
used to approximate the next best employment option for that executive
in the labor-market, the reservation wage. Pay is typically targeted at
the 50th, 75th, or 90th percentile of this group. The implicit
assumption is that a talented manager is interchangeable between firms,
and thus should be paid very nearly what other executives are paid.
But although the notion that talent is
a competitive market is both attractive and plausible, it is highly
questionable. Executive talent is not fully transferable
between companies. Scholars have long recognized a distinction between
firm-specific and general skills. It is quite apparent that successful
CEOs leverage not only their intrinsic talents but also, and more
importantly, a vast accumulation of firm-specific knowledge developed
over a multi-year career. Whether it is deep knowledge of an
organization's personnel or the processes specific to a particular
operation, this skill set is learned carefully over a long tenure with a
company and not easily capable of quick replication at other firms. In
fact, when "superstar" executives change companies, the result is
usually disappointing.
If this is true, then the CEO labor market is
less competitive than CEO compensation committees implicitly assume.
Executives are in fact to a great extent captive to their companies,
which ought to provide boards with scope for negotiating actively on
compensation rather than relying on peer comparisons. The best bargain
in corporate America, then, is not Al Dunlap's superstar CEO, but rather
the home-grown executive, with whom fair and modest pay is negotiated,
often less than suggested by peer comparisons.
Continued in article
Bob Jensen's threads about outrageous executive compensation are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
"Charles O'Reilly:
Narcissists Get Paid More Than You Do: New research explores why some CEOs
have such big salaries," Stanford Graduate School of Business, July 2014 ---
http://www.gsb.stanford.edu/news/headlines/charles-oreilly-narcissists-get-paid-more-than-you-do
Larry Ellison towered again among the top ranks
of the highest-paid CEOs in 2013 with total compensation of $78 million.
He is in plentiful company. Sixty-five chief executives took home annual
pay of more than $20 million last year. What prompts boards of directors
to grant such astounding sums? And why would individuals, who by any
objective measure have all their needs satisfied, seek such exaggerated
amounts?
New research by Stanford management professor
Charles A. O’Reilly
shows that it is the persuasive personality and aggressive “me first”
attitude embodied by narcissistic CEOs that helps them land bloated pay
packages. Specifically, narcissistic CEOs are paid more than their
non-narcissistic (and merely self-confident) peers. There is also a
larger gap between narcissists’ compensation and that of their top
management teams than is found with CEOs who do not display the trait.
The longer the narcissists have held the top post, the bigger the
differential, according to the
study
published in The Leadership Quarterly earlier this year.
Narcissism is a personality type characterized
by dominance, self-confidence, a sense of entitlement, grandiosity, and
low empathy. Narcissists naturally emerge as leaders because they embody
prototypical leadership qualities such as energy, self-assuredness, and
charisma.
“They don’t really care what other people
think, and depending on the nature of the narcissist, they are impulsive
and manipulative,” says O’Reilly, whose research examines grandiose
narcissism, a form associated with high extraversion and low
agreeableness.
The study that O’Reilly coauthored with UC
Berkeley doctoral student Bernadette Doerr, Santa Clara University
professor David F. Caldwell and UC Berkeley professor Jennifer A.
Chatman, surveyed employees in 32 large publicly traded technology
companies to identify the narcissistic CEOs among them. Employees filled
out personality assessments about their CEOs, which included rating the
chiefs’ degree of narcissistic qualities such as “self-centered,”
“arrogant,” and “conceited.”
They also completed a Ten Item Personality
Inventory (TIPI) about their CEOs. In addition, researchers scanned
CEOs’ shareholder letters and earnings call transcripts for an abundance
of self-referential pronouns such as “I.” Narcissists use first person
pronouns and personal pronouns more often than their non-narcissistic
peers, prior research shows.
The scholars chose to focus on the quickly
changing, high-stakes technology industry, in part because it prizes
individuals who are convinced of their own vision and who are willing to
take risks. They figured correctly that it would bolster narcissists
with large pay contracts. “In places like Silicon Valley, where
grandiosity is rewarded, we almost select for these people,” says
O’Reilly. “We want people who want to remake the world in their images.”
Narcissistic CEOs secure these pay contracts,
at least in part, by winning over board members. The study found that
companies with highly narcissistic top bosses do not necessarily perform
better than those led by less narcissistic chiefs.
Narcissistic CEO/founders obtained even larger
compensation than their narcissistic peers who didn’t found their
companies. O’Reilly says this is logical given the extreme
self-confidence and persistence of founders, who have to raise capital
and overcome obstacles in order to survive.
“From the board member’s perspective, you’ve
got this person who is quite charming, charismatic, self-confident,
visionary, action-oriented, able to make hard decisions (which means the
person doesn’t have a lot of empathy) and the board says, ‘This is a
great leader,’” O’Reilly says, adding that board members might not
necessarily see their self-serving, superficial qualities.
The paper notes that the CEO is often involved
in hiring a compensation consultant who sets the CEO’s pay. Thus, it is
in the consultant’s interest to make sure the chief is well paid.
Unencumbered by a sense of fairness toward others, narcissists believe
they are special and will often manipulate others in order to get large
pay contracts they believe is their due.
The study also found that the longer the
narcissistic chief executive was in charge, the farther ahead of his
team his pay progressed, because he had recurring exchanges with the
board, seeking more money for himself and less for his team.
A large pay divide between the CEO and other
top executives can chip away at company morale, leading to higher
employee turnover and lower satisfaction, according to O’Reilly’s
research. Given the dissatisfaction and protests this pay gap can breed
among employees, the researchers questioned how narcissistic CEOs could
occupy the big office for so long. While some employees leave on their
own accord, the paper supposes that CEOs may “eliminate those who might
challenge them or fail to acknowledge their brilliance.” The same lack
of empathy that makes narcissists less likeable to underlings also helps
these CEOs fire them with little guilt.
Continued in article
"The Pay-for-Performance Myth,"
By Eric Chemi and Ariana Giorgi, Bloomberg Businessweek, July 22, 2014
---
http://www.businessweek.com/articles/2014-07-22/for-ceos-correlation-between-pay-and-stock-performance-is-pretty-random?campaign_id=DN072214
Bonuses for What?
The only guy to make almost a $100 Million dollars at GE is the CEO who
destroyed shareholder value by nearly 50% in slightly less than a decade
"GE has been an investor disaster under Jeff Immelt," MarketWatch,
March 8, 2010 ---
http://www.marketwatch.com/story/ge-has-been-an-investor-disaster-under-jeff-immelt-2010-03-08
When things go well,
chief executives of major companies rack up hundreds of millions of dollars,
even billions, on their stock allotments and options.
It's always justified
on the grounds that they've created lots of shareholder value. But what
happens when things go badly?
For one example, take
a look at General Electric Co. /quotes/comstock/13*!ge/quotes/nls/ge (GE
16.27, +0.04, +0.22%) , one of America's biggest and most important
companies. It just revealed its latest annual glimpse inside the executive
swag bag.
By any measure of
shareholder value, GE has been a disaster under Jeffrey Immelt. Investors
haven't made a nickel since he took the helm as chairman and chief executive
nine years ago. In fact, they've lost tens of billions of dollars.
The stock, which was
$40 and change when Immelt took over, has collapsed to around $16. Even if
you include dividends, investors are still down about 40%. In real
post-inflation terms, stockholders have lost about half their money.
So it may come as a
shock to discover that during that same period, the 54-year old chief
executive has racked up around $90 million in salary, cash and pension
benefits.
GE is quick to point
out that Immelt skipped his $5.8 million cash bonus in 2009 for the second
year in a row, because business did so badly. And so he did.
Yet this apparent
sacrifice has to viewed in context. Immelt still took home a "base salary"
of $3.3 million and a total compensation of $9.9 million.
His compensation in
the previous two years was $14.3 million and $9.3 million. That included
everything from salary to stock awards, pension benefits and other perks.
Too often, the media
just look at each year's pay in isolation. I decided to go back and take the
longer view.
Since succeeding Jack
Welch in 2001, Immelt has been paid a total of $28.2 million in salary and
another $28.6 million in cash bonuses, for total payments of $56.8 million.
That's over nine years, and in addition to all his stock- and option-grant
entitlements.
It doesn't end there.
Along with all his cash payments, Immelt also has accumulated a remarkable
pension fund worth $32 million. That would be enough to provide, say, a
60-year-old retiree with a lifetime income of $192,000 a month.
Yes, Jeff Immelt has
been at the company for 27 years, and some of this pension was accumulated
in his early years rising up the ladder. But this isn't just his regular
company pension. Nearly all of this is in the high-hat plan that's only
available to senior GE executives.
Immelt's personal use
of company jets -- I repeat, his personal use for vacations, weekend
getaways and so on -- cost GE stockholders another $201,335 last year. (It's
something shareholders can think about when they stand in line to take off
their shoes at JFK -- if they're not lining up at the Port Authority for a
bus.)
Clawback ---
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Clawback
PwC: Executive Compensation: Clawbacks 2013 proxy disclosure
study ---
Click Here
http://www.pwc.com/us/en/cfodirect/issues/human-resources/clawbacks-2013-proxy-disclosure-study.jhtml?display=/us/en/cfodirect/issues/human-resources&j=444160&e=rjensen@trinity.edu&l=727944_HTML&u=17822686&mid=7002454&jb=0
"A Dangerous Pattern: Rewarding Failure," by Ron Kensas,
Harvard Business Review Blog, March 9, 2010 ---
http://blogs.hbr.org/ashkenas/2010/03/a-dangerous-pattern-rewarding.html?cm_mmc=npv-_-DAILY_ALERT-_-AWEBER-_-DATE
Over the past few months there has been growing
anger and frustration about outsized Wall Street bonuses awarded by
institutions that were rescued by taxpayer funds. At the core of this
anger is the feeling that the pursuit of big payoffs caused bankers to
develop complex products and take big risks which ultimately caused the
financial system to crash — and if this dynamic is not curbed, it will
happen again. At the same time, there is also a feeling, reinforced by
President Obama, that Wall Street bankers have not really been held
accountable for their risky actions and, in fact, are being unduly
rewarded while everyone else continues to suffer.
Unfortunately, the focus on Wall Street masks a
more dangerous pattern of rewarding failure that is deeply embedded in
the highest levels of corporate and governmental culture. For example,
President Obama's point person for reforming Wall Street is Treasury
Secretary Timothy Geithner. But somehow Geithner himself has not been
held accountable for the financial crisis. This is despite the fact that
as president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York Geithner was
responsible for the supervision of Wall Street banks. His reward for
allowing these banks to create unsustainable balance sheets: He was made
Treasury Secretary.
Similarly Geithner's boss in the Federal
Reserve, Ben Bernanke, was not held accountable for the interest rate
and regulatory policies that some say caused the crisis. Instead, he was
confirmed for a second term by a wide margin in the Senate. And to
complete the failure trifecta, Lawrence Summers, who supported many of
the policies that caused the financial crisis and resigned from his
position as President of Harvard after making unfortunate statements
about the capabilities of women, was given a senior role as a White
House economic policy advisor.
But this culture of rewarding failure is not
limited to the highest levels of government. Virtually every senior
corporate leader of a failed institution walks away with millions of
dollars. Many move on to other senior corporate jobs or board positions.
Take Robert Nardelli as an example. After not getting the top job at GE
in 2001, Nardelli became the CEO of Home Depot where he made a series of
strategic missteps and displayed an arrogance that alienated employees
and customers. After being ousted from that job (with millions of
dollars) he was hired by Cerberus to turn around Chrysler — another
failure which ultimately resulted in its acquisition by Fiat. And while
thousands of Chrysler employees and dealers lost their jobs and their
incomes, again Nardelli walked away with his fortune intact and
enhanced.
None of this is to blame Geithner, Bernanke,
Summers or Nardelli. The point of this argument is that at the highest
levels of government and corporations, we have accepted a culture of
rewarding failure. That is why perhaps the best job in America is to be
a failed CEO. You receive millions in severance and are once more given
opportunities to either try it again, or serve on a board of directors
where you can again escape accountability for failure. In fact, while
President Obama calls for "clawbacks" of banker's bonuses, nobody seems
to be calling for directors to return the compensation that they
received for poorly "supervising" financial institutions and other
corporations that struggle or fail.
Steve Kerr, former chief learning officer of GE
and Goldman Sachs, notes that the biggest problem with compensation is
what he calls "asking for A while rewarding B." If we are serious about
asking for excellent performance, then we have to stop rewarding
failure. It's a simple equation — and until we get it right, the
President's calls for greater accountability will have a hollow ring.
What do you think?
"Five Ways to Heal American Capitalism," by Roger Marti,
Harvard Business Review Blog, March 3, 2010 ---
http://blogs.hbr.org/cs/2010/03/healing_american_capitalism_to.html?cm_mmc=npv-_-DAILY_ALERT-_-AWEBER-_-DATE
Bob Jensen's threads on outrageous executive compensation are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
"How CEO Pay Became a Massive Bubble," An interview with Mihir
Desai Harvard Business School, Harvard Business Review Blog, February
23, 2012 ---
Click Here
http://blogs.hbr.org/ideacast/2012/02/how-ceo-pay-became-a-massive-b.html?referral=00563&cm_mmc=email-_-newsletter-_-daily_alert-_-alert_date&utm_source=newsletter_daily_alert&utm_medium=email&utm_campaign=alert_date
Question
Do big bonuses lead to worse performance?
"Does Bigger Bonus Equal Worse Performance?Around the turn of every year,
bankers can think of only one thing: the size of their bonuses," by Dan
Ariely, Wall Street Technology, June 18, 2010 ---
http://wallstreetandtech.com/career-management/showArticle.jhtml?articleID=225700612&cid=nl_wallstreettech_daily
Thanks Jagdish!
Around the turn of every year, bankers can
think of only one thing: the size of their bonuses.
Even beyond bonus season, they run different
scenarios and assumptions, trying to calculate their number.
This distracts them so much that the bigger the
bonus at stake, the worse the performance, according to behavioral
economist Dan Ariely, who lays out his theory in his new book "The
Upside of Irrationality" (HarperCollins, $27.99).
"For a long time we trained bankers to think
they are the masters of the universe, have unique skills and deserve to
be paid these amounts," said Ariely, who also wrote the New York Times
bestseller "Predictably Irrational."
"It is going to be hard to convince them that
they don't really have unique skills and that the amount they've been
paid for the past years is too much."
Ariely's findings come as regulators try to
rein in Wall Street's bonus culture after the 2008 financial collapse.
The financial industry argues it needs to pay large bonuses to attract
and motivate its top employees.
In an experiment in India, Ariely measured the
impact of different bonuses on how participants did in a number of tasks
that required creativity, concentration and problem-solving.
One of the tasks was Labyrinth, where the
participants had to move a small steel ball through a maze avoiding
holes. Ariely describes a man he identified as Anoopum, who stood to win
the biggest bonus, staring at the steel ball as if it were prey.
"This is very, very important," Anoopum mumbled
to himself. "I must succeed." But under the gun, Anoopum's hands
trembled uncontrollably, and he failed time after time.
A large bonus was equal to five months of their
regular pay, a medium-sized bonus was equivalent to about two weeks pay
and a small bonus was a day's pay.
There was little difference in the performance
of those receiving the small and medium-sized bonuses, while recipients
of large bonuses performed worst.
SHOCK TREATMENT
More than a century ago, an experiment with
rats in a maze rigged with electric shocks came to a similar conclusion.
Every day, the rats had to learn how to navigate a new maze safely.
When the electric shocks were low, the rats had
little incentive to avoid them. At medium intensity they learned their
environment more quickly.
But when the shock intensity was very high, it
seemed the rats could not focus on anything other than the fear of the
shock.
This may provide lessons for regulators who
want to change Wall Street's bonus culture, Ariely said. Paying no bonus
or smaller bonuses could help fix skewed incentives without loss of
talent.
"The reality is, a lot of places are able to
attract great quality people without paying them what bankers are paid,"
Ariely said. "Do you think bankers are inherently smarter than other
people? I don't." (Reporting by Kristina Cooke; Editing by Daniel Trotta)
Bob Jensen's threads on outrageous compensation are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
From The Wall Street Journal Accounting Weekly Review on October
29, 2010
Shareholders Hit the Roof Over Relocation Subsidies
by: Joann S. Lublin
Oct 25, 2010
Click here to view the full article on WSJ.com
TOPICS: Board of Directors, Corporate Governance, Executive
Compensation, Financial Reporting
SUMMARY: "Activist investors are turning up the heat on companies that
give relocating executives generous benefits to cover the cost of their
depressed home values....The root problem: The protracted housing
downturn in the U.S. is colliding with a rebound in management hiring.
So more employers help pick up the tab for relocated executives losing
money on their home sales." The issue could become more visible next
year with the implementation of the "say on pay" component of the
financial-overhaul legislation requiring shareholder advisory votes on
executive compensation.
CLASSROOM APPLICATION: The article is useful in any class covering
corporate governance and/or executive compensation.
QUESTIONS:
1. (Introductory) What benefits are being paid to top executives at many
U.S. corporations when they hire?
2. (Advanced) What investor groups are opposing these practices? Explain
who these investors groups are and how they help to all investors to
focus on governance issues such as this one. In your answer, also define
the notion of "corporate governance."
3. (Introductory) What is "say on pay"? When was a U.S. government
provision on "say on pay" implemented?
4. (Advanced) Why will "say on pay" requirements likely cause more of a
stir in corporate annual meetings with shareholders next year?
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
"Shareholders Hit the Roof Over Relocation Subsidies," by: Joann S. Lublin,
The Wall Street Journal, October25, 2010 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303864404575571972286910174.html?mod=djem_jiewr_AC_domainid
Activist investors are turning up the heat on
companies that give relocating executives generous benefits to cover the
cost of their depressed home values.
Microsoft Corp. and Wal-Mart Stores Inc. may
face investor criticism at their next annual meetings. So far this year,
proxy adviser Institutional Shareholder Services has urged investors to
oppose the re-election of directors who oversaw home-loss payouts at
eight concerns, including Electronic Arts Inc. and Boston Scientific
Corp. That's twice the number in 2009.
Home-loss subsidies could become more
contentious next year, when all U.S. public companies must hold an
advisory investor vote on executive pay—as mandated by the new
financial-overhaul law. ISS expects such payments will influence whether
it endorses executive-pay practices.
The root problem: The protracted housing
downturn in the U.S. is colliding with a rebound in management hiring.
So more employers help pick up the tab for relocated executives losing
money on their home sales.
Experience WSJ professional Editors' Deep Dive:
Shareholder Activism a Growing TrendMERGERS & ACQUISITIONS REPORT Proxy
Access Rules Create Uncertainty .New York Law Journal Dodd-Frank:
Selected Provisions on Executive Pay .The Legal Intelligencer Say on Pay
Is Here to Stay. Access thousands of business sources not available on
the free web. Learn More ."Home-loss provisions are a hot-button issue
with our institutional clients," explains Patrick McGurn, special
counsel for ISS. "We have been seeing extraordinary relocation payments
being made to bail out transferred executives."
Microsoft may see fireworks over the issue at
its annual meeting next month. Stephen Elop, recruited as president of
its business division in 2008, got $5.5 million in relocation benefits
and related tax payments. The package includes Microsoft's $3.7 million
loss on the 2009 sale of his seven-bathroom house in Los Altos Hills,
Calif.
Mr. Elop quit to run Nokia Corp. in September.
He had to repay $667,000 of his $2 million signing bonus because he
stayed less than three years, but Microsoft had only negotiated a
one-year "clawback" for his relocation package.
View Full Image
Reuters
Wal-Mart's Brian C. Cornell .The unrecovered
benefits aroused the ire of CtW Investment Group, an arm of labor
federation Change to Win, whose union pension funds own Microsoft
shares. Hefty home-sale subsidies reflect "the board's failure to
appropriately constrain the risk of such egregious non-performance
related payments," CtW said in an Oct. 15 letter to Dina Dublon,
chairman of Microsoft's board pay panel. The letter urged directors to
end home-loss relocation benefits and asked her to discuss similar
corrective measures during the annual meeting.
Microsoft "has taken steps to minimize that
kind of risk in the relocation program going forward," a spokesman says.
In a Friday regulatory filing, the company
announced identical recovery periods for relocation payments and signing
bonuses plus "reasonable caps" on relocation benefits. Those moves come
after the company had already responded to investor criticism by
extending relocation-aid clawbacks to two years shortly before its 2009
annual meeting.
William Patterson, CtW's executive director,
praises the changes but says "there's still room for improvement."
About 74% of companies reimburse some or all of
a staff member's home-sale loss, according to a March survey by Weichert
Relocation Resources Inc. of 185 companies. That's up from 63% in a
similar 2008 survey.
Nineteen companies divulged largely sizable
outlays for residential losses of a relocated senior officer in their
latest proxy statement, reports Equilar, an executive-compensation
research firm. Seven occurred at the 100 biggest businesses, ranging
from Delta Air Lines Inc. to Wal-Mart. No Fortune 100 concern disclosed
the reimbursements in their 2007 proxies.
Proponents defend the perk as necessary for
businesses to attract and keep star players. "They simply need those
executives to move," says James D.C. Barrall, head of the global
executive compensation and benefits practice at Latham & Watkins LLP.
Continued in article
"CEO Pay in FTSE 100: Pay Inequality, Board Size and Performance,"
by William Patrick Forbes, SSRN, September 1, 2012 ---
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2140204
Abstract: n this paper we examine the agency
costs of seemingly excessive pay awards to CEO's within the FTSE 100 in
the last decade. Are CEOs taking a large proportion of the total pot (a
big "pay slice") more, or less, able to return value to shareholders by
better management? In presenting this evidence we describe variations in
whole distribution of executive pay, rather than invoking some arbitrary
cut-off point (e.g. the CEO's pay as a percentage of their five highest
paid peers or the CPS), to determine how changes in shareholder value
match to concurrent changes in the distribution of executive pay. We ask
is the impact of executive pay-inequality a function of board size,
rendering the CPS measure problematic in this context? If so how does
the interaction of board size and corporate performance size, as
measured by shareholder returns, explain variation in the sensitivity of
the pay-performance relationship for UK FTSE executives? We advance the
Gini coefficient as a preferable measure of executive pay inequality in
order to capture the impact of perceived inequality upon corporate
performance.
Jensen Comment
Although the findings in this study in terms of CEO pay, I strongly object
to the Gini coefficient for comparison of poverty levels between countries.
For example, Canada and North Korea have roughly the same Gini coefficient.
Yeah Right! You get a higher Gini coefficient just for spreading the poverty
equally.
Having said that, I'm a long-time advocate for curbing excessive
executive compensation, especially those that reward failure and fraud ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
On CBS news last week, it was stated that Putin's in house in Russia cost a
mere $1 billion. When it comes to corruption, start at the top with
government.
This is the graph of political corruption.

Bob Jensen's threads on the American Dream ---
http://www.cs.trinity.edu/~rjensen/temp/SunsetHillHouse/SunsetHillHouse.htm
Our Broken Corporate Governance Model
"Why Executive Pay is So High," by Neil Weinberg, Forbes,
April 22, 2010 ---
http://www.forbes.com/forbes/2010/0510/outfront-pay-bosses-ceo-chairman-why-executives-pay-is-high.html?boxes=Homepagetoprated
How can investors reel in pay and get more out
of corporate bosses? Here's one view: Kick the chief executive out of
the boardroom.
When it comes to the way corporate boards
oversee chief executives--or, all too often, fail to--few people have as
many war stories to tell from as many vantage points as Gary Wilson. He
was Walt Disney Co. ( DIS - news - people )'s chief financial officer
and, as a director, the subject of scorn when its board was twice ranked
the worst in the country. As a Yahoo ( YHOO - news - people ) director
Wilson was targeted by investor Carl Icahn, who sought to oust the board
during a 2008 failed shotgun marriage with Microsoft ( MSFT - news -
people ). As a private equity guy he led the 1989 Northwest Airlines (
NWA - news - people ) buyout along with Alfred Checchi.
So Wilson can say, with more than a little
credibility, that the boards supposedly overseeing management are
instead packed with lackeys with appalling frequency. It's a familiar
complaint but one that he believes is responsible for out-of-control
pay, the short-term greed that helped spawn the recent financial
meltdown and a staggering waste of resources. Wilson's solution: Abolish
the joint role of chief executive and chairman and install independent
bosses to oversee boards.
"From what I've seen, managers are interested
in what goes into their pockets and willing to use lots of leverage to
add short-term profits, boost the stock price and sell their options,"
says Wilson, 70. "Long-term shareholders risk getting screwed."
The Alliance, Ohio native has joined up with
Ira Millstein, a Wall Street attorney, and Harry Pearse, former General
Motors general counsel and Marriott Corp. director, to push for
independent chairmen. Their platform is the Millstein Center for
Corporate Governance at Yale.
Does splitting the title benefit shareholders?
Evidence is inconclusive, but here's an indicator suggesting they're on
to something: 76% of the 25 bosses who rank lowest on our annual survey
comparing compensation to shareholder return hold dual titles. Only 44%
of the best 25 hold both titles. The dual players include Richard D.
Fairbank of Capital One, Ray Irani of Occidental Petroleum ( OXY - news
- people ), David C. Novak of Yum Brands and Howard Solomon of Forest
Labs. ( FRX - news - people ) Wilson and Pearse insist that they saw
boards transformed overnight from supplicants to independents when the
roles were separated at companies where they were directors.
Boards occasionally go through spasms of
feistiness. In 1992 General Motors' board ousted Robert Stemple as
chairman, which led to similar moves at American Express ( AXP - news -
people ), Westinghouse and other companies. But today only 21% of boards
are chaired by bona fide independents, says RiskMetrics Group, a New
York financial advisory firm that owns ISS Proxy Advisory Services. In
43% of big companies the roles are ostensibly split, but the chairman,
says RiskMetrics, is an ex-chief executive or otherwise defined as a
company "insider."
In some cases nothing less than corporate
survival is at stake, Wilson argues. He points to Lehman Brothers (
LEHMQ - news - people ), where Richard Fuld was chief executive and
chairman for 15 years and where management took the sorts of big risks
that ultimately sank the firm.
Wilson isn't against stock options but believes
in tying them to long-term returns with strike prices that rise at the
rate of inflation plus some risk premium, as he has done at some
companies he has invested in. That way management isn't rewarded just
for showing up.
Independent boards might also rein in pay. In
Europe Wilson sat on KLM's advisory board and says it's no coincidence
that (a) chief executives typically run a management board, which
reports up to the separate advisory board, and (b) pay is well below
U.S. levels. At many U.S. companies, he says, the combined boss often
recruits board members and then "directors feel obligated to the
CEO/chairman, make the friendliest member chairman of the compensation
committee and then hire a friendly consultant to do an analysis that
favors high management pay."
Continued in Article
Comment Letter from 80 Business and Law
Professors Regarding Corporate Governance
I submitted to the SEC yesterday a comment letter
on behalf of a bi-partisan group of eighty professors of law, business,
economics, or finance in favor of facilitating shareholder director
nominations. The submitting professors are affiliated with forty-seven
universities around the United States, and they differ in their view on many
corporate governance matters. However, they all support the SEC’s “proxy
access” proposals to remove impediments to shareholders’ ability to nominate
directors and to place proposals regarding nomination and election
procedures on the corporate ballot. The submitting professors urge the SEC
to adopt a final rule based on the SEC’s current proposals, and to do so
without adopting modifications that could dilute the value of the rule to
public investors.
Lucian Bebchuk, Harvard Law School, on Tuesday August 18, 2009 ---
Click Here
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate governance ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
Long Time WSJ Defenders of Wall Street's Outrageous Compensation Turn
Into Hypocrites
At each stage of the disaster, Mr. Black told me --
loan officers, real-estate appraisers, accountants, bond ratings agencies --
it was pay-for-performance systems that "sent them wrong." The need for new
compensation rules is most urgent at failed banks. This is not merely
because is would make for good PR, but because lavish executive bonuses
sometimes create an incentive to hide losses, to take crazy risks, and even,
according to Mr. Black, to "loot the place through seemingly normal
corporate mechanisms." This is why, he continues, it is "essential to
redesign and limit executive compensation when regulating failed or failing
banks." Our leaders may not know it yet, but this showdown between rival
populisms is in fact a battle over political legitimacy. Is Wall Street the
rightful master of our economic fate? Or should we choose a broader form of
sovereignty? Let the conservatives' hosannas turn to sneers. The market god
has failed.
Thomas Frank, "Wall Street Bonuses Are an Outrage: The public
sees a self-serving system for what it," The Wall Street Journal,
February 4, 2009 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123371071061546079.html?mod=todays_us_opinion
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate governance are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
"Golden coffins, golden offices, golden retirement: Ten of the most
egregious executive perks,"
by Allistair Barr, Market Watch, May 13, 2009 ---
http://www.marketwatch.com/story/golden-coffins-10-of-the-most-egregious-ceo-perks?pagenumber=1
Clawback Teaching Case: Earnings Management and Creative
Accounting
"Clawbacks: Prospective Contract Measures in an Era of Excessive
Executive Compensation and Ponzi Schemes," by Miriam A. Cherry and Jarrod
Wong, SSRN, August 23, 2009 ---
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1460104
Abstract:
In the spring of 2009, public outcry erupted over the multi-million
dollar bonuses paid to AIG executives even as the company was receiving
TARP funds. Various measures were proposed in response, including a 90%
retroactive tax on the bonuses, which the media described as a "clawback."
Separately, the term "clawback" was also used to refer to remedies
potentially available to investors defrauded in the multi-billion dollar
Ponzi scheme run by Bernard Madoff. While the media and legal
commentators have used the term "clawback" reflexively, the concept has
yet to be fully analyzed. In this article, we propose a doctrine of
clawbacks that accounts for these seemingly variant usages. In the
process, we distinguish between retroactive and prospective clawback
provisions, and explore the implications of such provisions for contract
law in general. Ultimately, we advocate writing prospective clawback
terms into contracts directly, or implying them through default rules
where possible, including via potential amendments to the law of
securities regulation. We believe that such prospective clawbacks will
result in more accountability for executive compensation, reduce
inequities among investors in certain frauds, and overall have a
salutary effect upon corporate governance.
Clawback in the Context of TARP ---
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Troubled_Asset_Relief_Program
On October 14, 2008, Secretary of the Treasury
Paulson and President Bush separately announced revisions in the TARP
program. The Treasury announced their intention to buy senior preferred
stock and warrants in the nine largest American banks. The shares would
qualify as Tier 1 capital and were non-voting shares. To qualify for
this program, the Treasury required participating institutions to meet
certain criteria, including: "(1) ensuring that incentive compensation
for senior executives does not encourage unnecessary and excessive risks
that threaten the value of the financial institution; (2) required
clawback of any bonus or incentive compensation paid to a senior
executive based on statements of earnings, gains or other criteria that
are later proven to be materially inaccurate; (3) prohibition on the
financial institution from making any golden parachute payment to a
senior executive based on the Internal Revenue Code provision; and (4)
agreement not to deduct for tax purposes executive compensation in
excess of $500,000 for each senior executive." The Treasury also bought
preferred stock and warrants from hundreds of smaller banks, using the
first $250 billion allotted to the program.
The first allocation of the TARP money was
primarily used to buy preferred stock, which is similar to debt in that
it gets paid before common equity shareholders. This has led some
economists to argue that the plan may be ineffective in inducing banks
to lend efficiently.[15][16]
In the original plan presented by Secretary
Paulson, the government would buy troubled (toxic) assets in insolvent
banks and then sell them at auction to private investor and/or
companies. This plan was scratched when Paulson met with United
Kingdom's Prime Minister Gordon Brown who came to the White House for an
international summit on the global credit crisis.[citation needed] Prime
Minister Brown, in an attempt to mitigate the credit squeeze in England,
merely infused capital into banks via preferred stock in order to clean
up their balance sheets and, in some economists' view, effectively
nationalizing many banks. This plan seemed attractive to Secretary
Paulson in that it was relatively easier and seemingly boosted lending
more quickly. The first half of the asset purchases may not be effective
in getting banks to lend again because they were reluctant to risk
lending as before with low lending standards. To make matters worse,
overnight lending to other banks came to a relative halt because banks
did not trust each other to be prudent with their money.[citation
needed]
On November 12, 2008, Secretary of the Treasury
Henry Paulson indicated that reviving the securitization market for
consumer credit would be a new priority in the second allotment
From The Wall Street Journal Accounting Weekly Review on August 13, 2010
Clawbacks Divide SEC
by:
Kara Scannell
Aug 07, 2010
Click here to view the full article on WSJ.com
TOPICS: Accounting,
Auditing, Executive Compensation, Restatement, Sarbanes-Oxley Act, SEC,
Securities and Exchange Commission, Stock Options
SUMMARY: During
the settlement with Dell, Inc. in which founder Michael Dell agreed to
pay a $4 million penalty without admitting or denying wrongdoing,
Commissioner Luis Aguilar raised the issue of "clawing back"
compensation to executives based on inflated earnings. "The SEC alleged
Mr. Dell hid payments from Intel Corp. that allowed the company to
inflate earnings....Under [Section 304 of the 2002 Sarbanes-Oxley law],
the SEC can seek the repayment of bonuses, stock options or profits from
stock sales during a 12-month period following the first time the
company issues information that has to be restated." The SEC has been
working on a formal policy to guide them in cases in which an executive
has not been accused of personal wrongdoing, "but hammering out a policy
acceptable to the five-member Commission...may be difficult." The
related article announced the clawback provision when it was enacted
into law in July and compares it to the previous requirements related to
executive compensation under Sarbanes-Oxley.
CLASSROOM APPLICATION: The
article covers topics in financial reporting related to restatement,
executive compensation topics, the Sarbanes-Oxley law, and the SEC's
recent enforcement efforts in general.
QUESTIONS:
1. (Introductory)
Based on the main and related article, define and describe a "clawback"
policy.
2. (Introductory)
Why will most publicly traded companies implement change as a result of
the new law and resultant SEC requirements?
3. (Advanced)
When must a company restate previously reported financial results? Cite
the authoritative accounting literature requiring this treatment.
4. (Advanced)
Describe one executive compensation plan impacted by reported financial
results. How would such a plan be impacted by a restatement?
5. (Introductory)
What is the difficulty with applying the new clawback provisions to
executive stock option plans? Based on the related article, how are
companies solving this issue?
6. (Advanced)
Is it possible that executives who are innocent of any wrongdoing could
be affected financially by these new clawback provisions? Do you think
that such executives should have to repay to their companies
compensation amounts received in previous years? Support your answer.
7. (Advanced)
Refer to the main article. Consider the specific case of Dell Inc.
founder Michael Dell. Do you believe Mr. Dell should have to return
compensation to the company? Support your answer.
8. (Introductory)
How do the new requirements under the financial reform law enacted in
July exceed the requirements of Sarbanes-Oxley? In your answer, include
one or two statements to define the Sarbanes-Oxley law.
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
RELATED ARTICLES:
Law Sharpens 'Clawback' Rules for Improper Pay
by JoAnn S. Lublin
Jul 25, 2010
Online Exclusive
"Clawbacks Divide SEC," by: Kara Scannell, The Wall Street Journal,
August 7, 2010 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703988304575413671786664134.html?mod=djem_jiewr_AC_domainid
A dispute over how to claw back pay from
executives at companies accused of cooking the books is roiling the
Securities and Exchange Commission.
Commissioner Luis Aguilar, a Democrat, has
threatened not to vote on cases where he thinks the agency is too lax,
people familiar with the matter said. That prompted the SEC to review
its policies for the intermittently used enforcement tool.
"The SEC ought to use all the tools at its
disposal to try to seek funds for deterrence," Mr. Aguilar said in an
interview on Tuesday. "It's important for us to the extent possible to
try to deter, and part of that means using tools Congress has given us."
The issue of clawbacks came up during the SEC's
recent settlement with Dell Inc. and founder Michael Dell, people
familiar with the matter said.
The SEC alleged Mr. Dell hid payments from
Intel Corp. that allowed the company to inflate earnings. He agreed to
pay a $4 million penalty to settle the case without admitting or denying
wrongdoing, but didn't return any pay.
Mr. Aguilar initially objected to the Dell
settlement, according to people familiar with the matter. It is unclear
whether the penalty—considered high by historical standards for an
individual—swayed Mr. Aguilar's vote or whether he removed himself from
the case.
In the interview, Mr. Aguilar spoke generally
about clawbacks and declined to discuss Dell or other specific cases.
A spokesman for the SEC declined to comment.
Section 304 of the 2002 Sarbanes-Oxley law gave
the SEC the ability to seek reimbursement of compensation from the chief
executive and chief financial officer of a company when it restates its
financial statements because of misconduct.
Under the law, the SEC can seek the repayment
of bonuses, stock options or profits from stock sales during a 12-month
period following the first time the company issues information that has
to be restated.
Last year, the SEC used the tool for the first
time against an executive who wasn't accused of personal wrongdoing.
In that case the SEC sued Maynard Jenkins, the
former chief executive of CSK Auto Corp., for $4 million in bonuses and
stock sales. Mr. Jenkins is fighting the allegations.
SEC attorneys have been working on a more
formal policy to guide them in such cases, people familiar with the
matter said. They were seeking to tie the amount of the clawback to the
period of wrongdoing, these people said.
Mr. Aguilar felt the emerging new policy wasn't
stringent enough and told the SEC staff he would recuse himself from
cases when he didn't agree with the enforcement staff's recommendations,
the people said.
Amid the standoff, SEC enforcement chief Robert
Khuzami has halted the initial policy and set up a committee to take
another look at the matter, the people said.
Hammering out a policy acceptable to the
five-member commission, which has split on recent high-profile cases,
may be difficult.
The divisions worry some within the SEC because
the absence of an agreement could affect cases in the pipeline,
especially on close calls where Mr. Aguilar's vote might be necessary to
go forward.
Mr. Aguilar's hard line on clawbacks was
bolstered by the Dodd-Frank law, signed by President Obama on July 21.
It says stock exchanges need to change listing standards to require
companies to have clawback policies in place that go further than the
Sarbanes-Oxley policy.
Section 954 of the law says that pay clawbacks
should apply to any current or former employee and instructs companies
to seek pay earned during the three-year period before a restatement "in
excess of what would have been paid to the executive under the
accounting restatement."
Since becoming a commissioner in late 2008, Mr.
Aguilar has called for a tougher enforcement approach, including a
rework of the agency's policy of seeking penalties against companies.
In a speech in May, Mr. Aguilar took up the
issue of executive pay in the context of the SEC's lawsuit against Bank
of America Corp. for failing to disclose to shareholders the size of
bonuses paid to Merrill Lynch executives. The bank agreed to pay $150
million to settle the matter.
Mr. Aguilar said that penalty "pales" in
comparison to the $5.8 billion in bonuses paid during the merger.
"Perhaps what should happen is that, when a
corporation pays a penalty, the money should be required to come out of
the budget and bonuses for the people or group who were the most
responsible," he said.
Bob Jensen's Fraud Updates are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudUpdates.htm
CEO Pay: How to get your bailout taxpayer cake and eat it too
The new Chrysler is among the first companies to
fall under rules outlined in February by Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner,
for companies getting "extraordinary assistance" from the Treasury that
would cap pay for top executives at $500,000, excluding restricted shares of
stock. The final rules for the limits have not been released. . . . Fiat CEO
Sergio Marchionne has already indicated he will replace Chrysler CEO Bob
Nardelli. But under the deal, any of Chrysler's top officers can be deemed a
Fiat employee who's "seconded" to Chrysler, and therefore take pay from Fiat
beyond any Treasury cap.
"Fiat plans to bypass U.S. exec pay limits," by Justin Hyde and Greg
Gardner, Freep.com, May 13, 2009---
http://www.freep.com/article/20090513/BUSINESS01/905130318
PS: Fiat is not putting up any cash to get control of Chrysler. What a
deal!
Bob Jensen's threads on options accounting scandals are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Outrageous Bonus Frenzy
AIG now says it paid out more than $454 million
in bonuses to its employees for work performed in 2008. That is nearly four
times more than the company revealed in late March when asked by POLITICO to
detail its total bonus payments. At that time, AIG spokesman Nick Ashooh
said the firm paid about $120 million in 2008 bonuses to a pool of more than
6,000 employees. The figure Ashooh offered was, in turn, substantially
higher than company CEO Edward Liddy claimed days earlier in testimony
before a House Financial Services Subcommittee. Asked how much AIG had paid
in 2008 bonuses, Liddy responded: “I think it might have been in the range
of $9 million.”
Emon Javers, "AIG bonuses four
times higher than reported," Politico, May 5, 2009 ---
http://www.politico.com/news/stories/0509/22134.html
"Let's Move Their Cheese: We can get better bank management for a
fraction of the cost," The Wall Street Journal on May 6, 2009
---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124157594861790347.html
Incentives work, all right. Just look
at the way our bankers come back to bonuses, finding in every occasion a
good opportunity to cut themselves a slice of largess. Their
determination is unrelenting, monomaniacal. It's like Republicans
returning to tax cuts, the universal solution to every problem.
Some institutions, we read, are
struggling to free themselves from the TARP, because of its
exuberance-chilling compensation limits. Others have decimated their
workforces, apparently so they might continue to shower money on the
favored ones. Still other institutions have signaled that they would
rather borrow at higher rates of interest than accept the compensation
limits that come with cheaper federal loans. And certain banks are on
track to return to pre-recession compensation levels this year,
according to a story last week in the New York Times. Goldman Sachs, for
example, set aside $4.7 billion for compensation in the first quarter
alone.
Another way incentives work is this:
They have kept the debate over incentives from getting off the dime for
years. There is no amount of shame that will deter the bonus class from
pressing their demand, no scandal that will put it off limits, no public
outrage over AIG or Enron or really expensive Merrill Lynch trash cans
that will silence the managers' monotonous warble: "Attract and retain
top talent!"
And there is no possible objection to
inflated compensation you can make that will not be instantly maligned
as senseless populism.
In truth, however, the verdict has
been in for years. Pay for performance systems, at least as they exist
in many places, are a recipe for disaster.
What they have "incentivized"
executives to do, in countless cases, is not to perform, but to game the
system, to smooth the numbers, to take insane risks with other people's
money, to do whatever had to be done to ring the bell and send the
dollars coursing their way into the designated bank account.
It may well be true that those in our
bonus class are geniuses, but in far too many cases their fantastic
brain power is focused not on serving shareholders or guiding our
economy but simply on getting that bonus.
One might say that events of the last
year had proved this fairly conclusively.
Or one could quote the immortal words
of Franklin Raines, the onetime CEO of Fannie Mae, as they were recorded
by Business Week in 2003: "My experience is where there is a one-to-one
relation between if I do X, money will hit my pocket, you tend to see
people doing X a lot. You've got to be very careful about that. Don't
just say: 'If you hit this revenue number, your bonus is going to be
this.' It sets up an incentive that's overwhelming. You wave enough
money in front of people, and good people will do bad things."
Will they ever. They might, for
example, pull an accounting fraud of the kind Fannie Mae itself was
accused of committing in 2004, in which earnings were allegedly
manipulated to, ahem, hit certain revenue numbers and make the bonuses
go bang.
They might rig the game to take the
credit -- and reap the rewards -- when good luck befalls an entire
industry. If they're bankers, they might even try to claim that their
firm's recovery, made possible by TARP money and government guarantees,
was actually a fruit of their personal ingenuity. Bring on the billions!
Of course, they will also threaten to
leave if they don't get exactly what they want. Take last week's news
story about the supersuccessful energy trading unit of Citibank, whose
star trader scored $125 million in 2005, owns a castle in Germany, and
collects Julian Schnabel paintings. This merry band of traders is
apparently thinking about a white-collar walkout should the government
refuse to lift its compensation restrictions.
At first one feels pity for Citi and
its resident geniuses, brought to these straits by the interfering hand
of government. But then it dawns on you: Should a company receiving
billions of public dollars really be gambling on speculative energy
trades? After all, the bank's ordinary, everyday deposits would have to
be made good by you and me through the FDIC should one of their bright
traders pull a Nick Leeson someday.
Besides, why is Citi so anxious to
give in to these guys? It can't be that hard to "retain top talent" when
New York is awash with unemployed bankers and traders who are no doubt
anxious for a chance to prove their own brilliance.
Here's a Wall Street solution to Wall
Street's problems: Let's offshore trading operations to lands where
ethics are more highly esteemed -- Norway, for instance. And while we're
at it, let's replace our gold-plated, Lear-jetting American CEOs with
thrifty Europeans, who may not write management books but who will do
the work better, and for a fraction of the cost.
Richard Campbell notes a nice white collar crime blog edited by some law
professors ---
http://lawprofessors.typepad.com/whitecollarcrime_blog/
"Executive Compensation and
Boards of Directors," by J. Edward Ketz, SmartPros, July 2009
---
http://accounting.smartpros.com/x67023.xml
It
has been amazing to listen to the discourse over executive compensation
during the past year or so. On one side we have the pure capitalists who
tell us that government ruins everything, neatly forgetting that
unbridled capitalism exploits those with little power and ignoring the
fact that many CEOs do not provide enough value to shareholders to
justify their compensation. On the other extreme we have those who trust
government to cure all ills, overlooking the idiocy of many bureaucrats
and the possibility of a dangerous slide toward totalitarianism. We
shall not find a solution at either end of this spectrum.
The
Bush administration leaned toward the pure capitalists by appointing
Harvey Pitt and Christopher Cox to head the SEC. Both of them slept
during scandalous times, Enron and WorldCom occurring on Pitt’s watch
and the collapse of the banking industry on Cox’s. They failed
shareholders by allowing CEOs to run roughshod over the investors.
The
Obama administration wants to intervene by setting maximum compensation
levels for corporate managers and to regulate bonuses. It may come as a
shock to this administration and its supporters, but neither Obama nor
anybody on his team is omniscient. They just do not have a sufficient
knowledge of business and economics to determine these parameters. In
fact, some of the decisions already made are so faulty that one wonders
just how much economics anybody in this administration understands
(increasing the deficit by more than the deficits produced by all
previous presidents combined and attempting to pass an energy tax during
a recession are two examples).
It
is no wonder the public is starting to stir over the compensation
issue—some CEOs are indeed overpaid. While numerous current examples
exist, my favorite illustration remains Sprint in 2003. Somehow Sprint
CEO William Esrey and President Ronald LeMay finagled the firm to give,
and the board of directors to approve, so many stock options that they
made approximately $1.9 billion. Clearly, the two of them did not add
that much value to the firm! But the question is what to do about these
problems.
After lying dormant on this issue for years, the SEC on July 1 voted 5-0
to require business entities that received bailout money to permit
shareholders to vote on executive pay {http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2009/2009-147.htm}.
They also voted to require all SEC registrants to disclose more
information about executive compensation. These issues must still be
aired in public for two months before becoming final. This is a step in
the right direction as it attempts to deal with the issue but without
having Big Brother dictate the actual salary and bonus.
The
SEC proposal is quite disappointing, however, because the vote is
nonbinding. Given that, I’m not sure what the point is. It is almost as
if they want to fail so that Big Brother will have to intervene and set
prices for all of us.
What
the SEC and Congress and the President should be doing is creating
incentives and disincentives so that the economic system would function
more smoothly. They should stay out of the details because they don’t
have the knowledge to make the right decisions and because we would like
to keep some freedoms in our society. Perhaps they should read Hayek’s
The Road to Serfdom.
The
central problem continues to be the enervation of shareholders by the
management class. We need to rectify this imbalance and empower the
shareholders to regain control over their own companies. After all, they
are the owners!
The
other thing to do is to put some fire under the directors at corporate
enterprises. The board of directors supposedly represents the
shareholders, but often belies that point by assisting mangers in their
grab for power and wealth. The Congress could help by enacting
legislation that would allow investors to sue directors when the
directors abrogate their duties to the shareholders. (Recall that the
Supreme Court greatly restricted the liability of directors in Central
Bank of Denver v. First Interstate Bank of Denver.)
Of
course, the impotence of most boards of directors is frequently the
consequence of allowing managers to choose their buddies to be on the
board. “Independent directors” is a joke; I don’t if very many of them
are really independent. So another thing that should be done is to give
shareholders the right to vote for the directors. And not with a
manager-stacked deck of choices as if we lived in some communist
country. Give the shareholders the opportunity to add candidates to the
ballot. Again, they are the owners!
The
executive compensation issue remains a hot-button item. But it cannot be
ignored by the pure capitalists nor remedied by the governments’
controlling the price of labor. A more moderate approach is appropriate.
I think the key institution in this matter is the board of directors. If
empowered and if held accountable for their decisions, I think the board
of directors could properly address the issue of executive compensation.
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate governance are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
"The Case for Cutting the Chief's Paycheck," by William J.
Holstein, The New York Times, January 29, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/01/29/business/yourmoney/29advi.html
Yet Again the SEC Amends Executive Compensation Disclosure (particularly
regarding stock options)
The US Securities and Exchange Commission has
amended its executive and director compensation disclosure rules to more closely
conform the reporting of stock and option awards to FASB Statement No. 123
(revised 2004) Share-Based Payment. FAS 123R is similar to IFRS 2 Share-based
Payment. The amendment modifies rules that were adopted in July 2006.
SEC Press Release 2006 219 ---
http://www.iasplus.com/usa/0612seccomp.pdf
Bob Jensen's threads
on accounting for employee
stock options are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Bank of America pays $33M SEC fine over Merrill bonuses
Bank of America Corp. has agreed to pay a $33
million penalty to settle government charges that it misled investors about
Merrill Lynch's plans to pay bonuses to its executives, regulators said
Monday. In seeking approval to buy Merrill, Bank of America told investors
that Merrill would not pay year-end bonuses without Bank of America's
consent. But the Securities and Exchange Commission said Bank of America had
authorized New York-based Merrill to pay up to $5.8 billion in bonuses. That
rendered a statement Bank of America mailed to 283,000 shareholders of both
companies about the Merrill deal "materially false and misleading," the SEC
said in a statement.
Yahoo News, August 3, 2009 ---
http://news.yahoo.com/s/ap/20090803/ap_on_bi_ge/us_bank_of_america_sec
Professor Blinder, a professor of economics and public affairs at
Princeton University and vice chairman of the Promontory Interfinancial
Network, is a former vice chairman of the Federal Reserve Board ---
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Alan_S._Blinder
"When Greed Is Not Good: Wall Street has quickly rediscovered
the virtues of mammoth paychecks. Why hasn't there been more financial
reform?" by Alan S. Blinder, The Wall Street Journal, January 11,
2010 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703652104574652242436408008.html?mod=djemEditorialPage
I hear Gordon Gekko is making a comeback. So is
greed.
They say markets are alternately ruled by greed
and fear. Well, our panic-stricken financial markets have been ruled by
fear for so long that a little greed might serve as an elixir. But
everybody knows you can overdose on an elixir.
When economists first heard Gekko's now-famous
dictum, "Greed is good," they thought it a crude expression of Adam
Smith's "Invisible Hand"—which is one of history's great ideas. But in
Smith's vision, greed is socially beneficial only when properly
harnessed and channeled. The necessary conditions include, among other
things: appropriate incentives (for risk taking, etc.), effective
competition, safeguards against exploitation of what economists call
"asymmetric information" (as when a deceitful seller unloads junk on an
unsuspecting buyer), regulators to enforce the rules and keep
participants honest, and—when relevant—protection of taxpayers against
pilferage or malfeasance by others. When these conditions fail to hold,
greed is not good.
Plainly, they all failed in the financial
crisis. Compensation and other types of incentives for risk taking were
badly skewed. Corporate boards were asleep at the switch. Opacity
reduced effective competition. Financial regulation was shamefully lax.
Predators roamed the financial landscape, looting both legally and
illegally. And when the Treasury and Federal Reserve rushed in to
contain the damage, taxpayers were forced to pay dearly for the mistakes
and avarice of others. If you want to know why the public is enraged,
that, in a nutshell, is why.
American democracy is alleged to respond to
public opinion, and incumbents are quaking in their boots. Yet we stand
here in January 2010 with virtually the same legal and regulatory system
we had when the crisis struck in the summer of 2007, with only minor
changes in Wall Street business practices, and with greed returning big
time. That's both amazing and scary. Without major financial reform,
"it" can happen again.
It is true that regulators are much more
watchful now, that Bernie Madoff is in jail (where he should have more
company), and that much of "fancy finance" died a violent death in the
marketplace. All good. But history shows that financial markets have a
remarkable ability to forget the past and revert to their bad old ways.
And we've made essentially no progress on lasting financial reform.
View Full Image
Chad Crowe Perhaps reformers just need more
patience. The Treasury made a fine set of proposals that the president's
far-flung agenda left him little time to pursue—so far. The House of
Representatives passed a pretty good financial reform bill late last
year. And while there's been no action in the Senate as yet, at least
they are talking about it. As Yogi Berra famously said, "it ain't over
'til it's over."
But I'm worried. The financial services
industry, once so frightened that it scurried under the government's
protective skirts, is now rediscovering the virtues of laissez faire and
the joys of mammoth pay checks. Wall Street has mounted ferocious
lobbying campaigns against virtually every meaningful aspect of reform,
and their efforts seem to be paying off. Yes, the House passed a good
bill. Yet it would have been even better but for several changes
Financial Services Committee Chairman Barney Frank (D., Mass.) had to
make to get it through the House. Though the populist political pot was
boiling, lobbyists earned their keep.
I expect they'll earn more. Even before Senate
Banking Committee Chairman Christopher Dodd (D., Conn.) announced his
retirement, it appeared likely that any bill that could survive the
Senate would be weaker than the House bill. Then came Mr. Dodd's
announcement, which reshuffled the deck.
There are two diametrically opposed hypotheses
about how his retirement will affect the legislation. Conventional
wisdom holds that it is good news for reformers: Freed from crass
political concerns, Mr. Dodd can now steer his committee more firmly
toward a better bill. Let's hope so. But an opposing view reminds us
that lame ducks lose power rapidly in power-mad Washington. To lead,
someone must be willing to follow.
My fear is that a once-in-a-lifetime
opportunity to build a sturdier and safer financial system is slipping
away. Let's remember what happened to health-care reform (a success
story!) as it meandered toward 60 votes in the Senate. The world's
greatest deliberative body turned into a bizarre bazaar in which
senators took turns holding the bill hostage to their pet cause (or
favorite state). With zero Republican support, every one of the 60
members of the Democratic caucus held an effective veto—and several used
it.
If financial reform receives the same
treatment, we are in deep trouble, both politically and substantively.
To begin with the politics, recent patterns
make it all too easy to imagine a Senate bill being bent toward the will
of Republicans—who want weaker regulation—but then garnering no
Republican votes in the end. We've seen that movie before. If the sequel
plays in Washington, passing a bill will again require the votes of
every single Democrat plus the two independents. With veto power thus
handed to each of 60 senators, the bidding war will not be pretty.
On substance, while both health-care and
financial reform are complex, health care at least benefited from broad
agreement within the Democratic caucus on the core elements: expanded
but not universal coverage, subsidies for low-income families, enough
new revenue to pay the bills, insurance exchanges, insurance reform
(e.g., no denial of coverage for pre-existing conditions), and
experiments in cost containment to "bend the curve." The fiercest
political fights were over peripheral issues like the public option,
abortion rights (how did that ever get in there?), and whether
Nebraskans should pay like other Americans (don't try to explain that
one to foreigners).
But financial regulatory reform is not like
that. Every major element is contentious: a new resolution authority for
ailing institutions, a systemic risk regulator, a separate consumer
protection agency, whether to clip the Fed's wings or broaden them,
restrictions on executive compensation, regulation of derivatives,
limits on proprietary trading, etc.
The elements are interrelated; you can't just
pick one from column A and two from column B. What's worse, several
components would benefit from international cooperation—for example,
consistent regulation of derivatives across countries. This last point
raises the degree of difficulty substantially. No one worried about
international agreement while Congress was writing a health-care bill.
All and all, enacting sensible, comprehensive
financial reform would be a tall order even if our politics were more
civil and bipartisan than they are. To do so, at least a few
senators—Republicans or Democrats—will have to temper their
partisanship, moderate their parochial instincts, slam the door on the
lobbyists, and do what is right for America. Figure the odds. Gordon
Gekko already has.
Bob Jensen's threads on outrageous executive compensation are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
Fodder for Accounting and Finance Agency Theorists to Digest
Principle-Agent Theory ---
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Agency_Theory
In political science and economics, the
principal-agent problem or agency dilemma treats the difficulties that
arise under conditions of incomplete and asymmetric information when a
principal hires an agent. Various mechanisms may be used to try to align
the interests of the agent with those of the principal, such as piece
rates/commissions, profit sharing, efficiency wages, performance
measurement (including financial statements), the agent posting a bond,
or fear of firing. The principal-agent problem is found in most
employer/employee relationships, for example, when stockholders hire top
executives of corporations. Numerous studies in political science have
noted the problems inherent in the delegation of legislative authority
to bureaucratic agencies. Especially since bureaucrats often have
expertise that legislators and executives lack, laws and executive
directives are open to bureaucratic interpretation, creating
opportunities and incentives for the bureaucrat-as-agent to deviate from
the preferences of the constitutional branches of government. Variance
in the intensity of legislative oversight also serves to increase
principal-agent problems in implementing legislative preferences.
Four principles of contract design
- 3.1 Informativeness Principle
- 3.2 Incentive-Intensity Principle
- 3.3 Monitoring Intensity Principle
- 3.4 Equal Compensation Principle
- 3.5 A linear model
- 3.6 Nonlinearities
"Compensation Under Competition," by Richard Posner, The Becker-Posner
Blog, April 7, 2008 ---
http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/
There is a long-standing concern that corporate
executives are more risk averse than a corporation's shareholders,
because the latter can eliminate firm-specific risk by holding a
diversified portfolio, while the former cannot, because they have
firm-specific human capital that they will lose if the firm tanks. The
solution to this problem was thought to consist in making stock options
a large part of the executive's compensation, so that his incentives
would be closely aligned with those of the shareholders. True, because
he would bear more risk, he would have to be paid more in total
compensation than if he did not receive a large part of his compensation
in the form of stock options. But the cost to the corporation of the
additional pay would presumably be offset by the gain to the
shareholders from the executives' enhanced incentives to maximize
shareholder wealth.
But we are beginning to realize that the grant
of stock options may make corporate executives take more risks than the
shareholders desire [Jensen insert: To say
nothing of cheating on earnings reports].
Suppose that instead of being compensated for bearing risk just by being
paid a higher salary or given even more stock options, the executive is
guaranteed generous retirement and severance benefits that are
unaffected by the price of the corporation’s stock. Now he has a hedge
against risk, and can take more risks in operating the corporation
because his personal downside risk has been truncated. Perhaps this was
a factor in the recent stock market bubbles--the one that burst in 2000
with the crash of the high-tech stocks and the one that burst this year
as a result of the collapse of the subprime mortgage market and the
resulting credit crunch. A bubble is both a repellent and a lure. It is
a lure because during the bubble values are rising steeply, so an
investor who exits before the bubble has peaked may be leaving a good
deal of money on the table. He will be especially loath to do that if he
is hedged against the consequences of the bubble's eventual bursting.
Boards of directors could devise compensation
schemes that limited the attractiveness of risky undertakings, but they
have little incentive to do so. The boards tend to be dominated by CEOs
and other high corporate executives of other firms, who have an interest
in keeping executive compensation high and who are abetted by
compensation consultants who naturally recommend generous compensation
packages to directors who are recipients of generous compensation and
therefore believe that the CEOs of the companies on whose boards they
sit should be paid top dollar.
It is not clear what the free-market antidote
to this tendency to ratchet up executive compensation is. The
compensation of the CEO and other high officials of a large corporation
is usually only a small part of the corporation's costs, so shaving such
compensation is unlikely to be a powerful competitive weapon. But more
important, what rival corporation would have the governance structure
that would enable such shaving to be accomplished by overcoming the
obstacles that I have discussed? The private-equity firm is a partial
answer, because it has only a few shareholders and so need not delegate
compensation to a board of directors that has other interests besides
the welfare of the shareholders at heart. The reason it is only a
partial answer is that there are too few owners of capital who want or
have the ability or experience to participate as actively in management
as the private-equity entrepreneurs and there are too many efficiently
large corporations for all of them to have the good fortune of being
owned by a handful of entrepreneurial investors. There is a vast pool of
passive equity capital that can be put to work only in companies that
are organized in the traditional board-governed corporate form.
Here is another though related example of a
stubborn efficiency-in-compensation problem, also in a highly
competitive sector of the economy: law-firm billing practices. Major law
firms, with few exceptions, base their bills to their clients on the
number of hours that the firm's lawyers work on the client's case or
other project. In other words, they bill on the basis of inputs rather
than outputs. This is rational when output is difficult to evaluate, as
is often the case with a law firm's output because of the uncertainty of
litigation (in nonlitigation practice, because of legal and factual
uncertainties). The fact that a firm loses a case doesn't mean that it
did a bad job; both the winner's firm and the loser's firm may have done
equally good jobs--the lawyers don't control the outcome. A law firm can
give the client a pretty good idea of the quality of the lawyers it
assigns to the client's case, because there are observable proxies for a
lawyer's unobservable quality, proxies such as his educational and
employment history. What the client cannot readily judge is whether the
law firm put in excessive hours on the case, and the result, according
to persistent and cumulatively persuasive anecdotage, is a tendency for
law firms to invest hours in a case beyond the point at which the
marginal value of the additional hour is just equal to the marginal cost
to the client. Young lawyers often feel that they are being assigned
work to do that has little value to the client but that will increase
the firm's income because the firm bills its lawyers' time at a
considerably higher rate than the cost of that time to the firm. The
very high turnover at many law firms is attributed in part to
dissatisfaction of young lawyers with the amount of busywork that they
are assigned, work that bores them and does not contribute to the
development of their professional skills, yet may be very
time-consuming.
The problem is compounded by the distorted
incentives of corporate general counsels. A general counsel wants to
show his boss, the corporate CEO, that he monitors expenses carefully,
and, since he knows that he is likely to lose at least some of his
cases, he also wants to be able to avoid if possible being blamed by his
boss for the loss. Hourly billing serves both of these ends. The law
firm and the general counsel play a little game, in which the law firm
prices its hours on the assumption that it will not be able to collect
its billing rates on all of them, and the general counsel reduces the
number of hours that he is willing to pay for. He can then show his CEO
that he squeezed the water out of the law firm's bills. At the same
time, by paying a prominent law firm by the hour, he can assure his CEO,
in the event a case is lost, that he had told the firm to do as much
work as was needed to maximize the likelihood of a favorable outcome,
rather than paying a fixed rate agreed to at the outset that might have
induced the law firm to skimp on the amount of work it put into the
case.
One can imagine a law firm's adopting a
different method of pricing, in which it would charge at the outset a
fixed fee, subject to adjustments up or down at the end of the case
based on outcome, amount of work, or some other performance measure or
combination of such measures. The conventional law firm billing system
is a form of cost-plus pricing, which is considered wasteful. But
litigation is risky, and cost-plus pricing diminishes risk by
eliminating a contractor's incentive to cut corners. If the disutility
of risk to a general counsel is great, he will prefer to "overpay" law
firms rather than trying to explain to the CEO that the novel
compensation deal that he worked out with the law firm that lost the
case was not a factor in the loss; that he had not been penny wise and
pound foolish.
Although the compensation practices that I have
described seem inefficient, it does not follow that corrective measures
would be appropriate. They would be costly and the net benefits might
well be negative. It is efficient to live with a good deal of
inefficiency. Stated otherwise, the fact that competitive markets
contain large pockets of inefficiency is not in itself inefficient. For
example, while cartel pricing is inefficient, if the cost of preventing
cartelization exceeded the benefits one wouldn't want to prevent it. Yet
cartel pricing would still be inefficient in the sense of misallocating
resources, relative to the allocation under competition. We must live
with a good deal of inefficiency, but it is still inefficiency.
Continued in article
"Compensation Under Competition," by Nobel Laureate Gary Becker, The
Becker-Posner Blog, April 7, 2008 ---
http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/
Executive compensation has been criticized both
for being too generous, and for encouraging excessive risk-taking
relative to the desires of stockholders. Yet while there are links
between the level of pay and the amount of risk chosen, these are mainly
distinct issues. Executives may be paid little, but the pay can be
structured to have a much better payoff when profits are high than when
profits are low. In this case, the average level of pay over both good
and bad times would not be particularly generous, but its structure
would tend to encourage risk-taking behavior. On the other hand, a CEO's
pay might be excessively high on average, but not appreciable better
when his company does well than when it does badly. He would be
overpaid, but he would not have a financial incentive to take much
risks.
Does the pay structure in American
corporations, with the growing emphasis during the past several decades
on stock options, bonuses, and severance and retirement pay, encourage
excessive risk-taking, where "excessive" is defined relative to the
desires of stockholders? It may look that way now with the sizable
number of major financial companies that have taken huge write downs in
their mortgage-backed and other assets, while top executives of some of
these companies have only had modest declines in their pay (although
others, such as the head of Bears Sterns, have taken huge hits).
However, these financial difficulties do not necessarily imply that
heads of most financial companies knowingly engaged in more speculative
activities than desired by stockholders because of the incentives CEOs
had. A more compelling explanation is that heads of companies have
undervalued the risks involved in holding derivatives and other exotic
securities, particularly securities that were rather new and not well
understood. Let me stress, however, that I am not trying to excuse the
many CEOs in the financial sector and in other sectors who got off much
too easily for terrible investment decisions.
Bubbles are prolonged periods of excessive
optimism where the true longer-term risk to holding particular assets is
generally underestimated. The housing boom of the past few years now
appears to have been a serious bubble where pervasive optimism about
housing price movements raised the rate of increase in housing prices
far beyond sustainable levels. Sophisticated lenders as well as
low-income borrowers underestimated the risks involved in the
residential housing market, as they appeared to have assumed that
housing prices would continue to rise for a number of years in excess of
ten percent per year.
Evidence suggesting that the risk taken by
companies during the recent boom was not mainly due to a principal-agent
problem between executives and stockholders is that the major private
equity firms also experienced serious loses on their investments,
especially on their housing investments. Private equity companies have
much less of a principal-agent problem than do Citicorp, Bears Sterns
and other publicly traded companies because private equity companies
have a concentrated ownership. Also borrowers in the residential housing
market have basically no principal-agent problems since they buy for
themselves; yet many of them too took on excessive risk because of undo
optimism about the housing market.
The private equity example provides a more
general way to test whether CEOs take greater risks than their
stockholders desire. One can analyze the relation between the degree of
concentration of stock ownership in different companies and various
measures of risk, such as their year-to-year variance earnings, adjusted
for industry and other relevant determinants of this variance. The
excessive risk argument would suggest that the more concentrated the
ownership, the smaller would be the actual exposure to earnings and
asset risk.
Another test of the excessive risk argument is
whether the trend toward greater compensation in the form of stock
options and other performance contingent compensation increased the risk
taking of companies. Some have attributed much of the dot-com bubble to
increased performance based compensation. However, most dot-com
companies that went under were quite small and rather closely held by
venture capitalists and similar investors. Hence these companies did not
have a sharp conflict between stockholders and managers. Moreover,
during the dot-com bubble, assets of minor Internet companies were
raised in market value to more than 100 times earnings, even when they
had no sales, let alone earnings. Such huge earnings-profits ratios
suggest excessive risk taking by stockholders more than by managers.
Economic theory does imply that the increasing
trend toward performance-based compensation would increase the degree of
risk-taking by top executives. It is much less clear whether this effect
is large- doubts are expressed by Canice Prendergast in his study "The
Tenuous Trade-Off Between Risk And Incentives", Journal of Political
Economy, 2002, (Oct), 1071-1102. It is also unclear if CEOs have been
induced to take more risks than the level of risk desired by
stockholders. Furthermore, and most important, there is no persuasive
evidence that the structure of CEO compensation played an important roll
in either the dot-com or housing bubbles.
Bob Jensen's threads on accounting for employee stock options are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Teaching Case: A Real World Example of Zero-Based
Budgeting
Unease Brewing at Anheuser as New Owners Slash Costs
by
David Kesmodel and Suzanne Vranica
The Wall Street Journal
Apr 29, 2009
Click here to view the full article on WSJ.com ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124096182942565947.html?mod=djem_jiewr_AC
TOPICS: Budgeting,
Cost Accounting, Cost Management, Managerial Accounting
SUMMARY: At
Anheuser-Busch in St. Louis, Missouri, "...executives and others now
work a few feet apart" at clustered desks after new owners InBev
eliminated executive perks, demolished plush offices, and began
requiring sharing secretarial services. "...InBev has turned a
family-led company that spared little expense into one that is
focused entirely on cost-cutting and profit margins, while
rethinking the way it sells beer."
CLASSROOM APPLICATION: The
article includes a discussion of zero-based budgeting that can be
used in managerial accounting course covering the topic.
QUESTIONS:
1. (Introductory)
Who is InBev? How was the company formed? What iconic American beer
brands are now owned by this company?
2. (Introductory)
What cultural differences are evident between owners of InBev and
Anheuser-Busch? What factors do you think lead to these cultural
differences?
3. (Introductory)
How has InBev "focused on cost-cutting and profit margins"? Cite all
points in the article related to these strategies. In your answer,
define the term "profit margin" as it relates to the strategies
being undertaken.
4. (Advanced)
What is zero-based budgeting? How does that process help to focus on
cost-cutting efforts?
5. (Advanced)
What strategies indicate that InBev is "rethinking the way it sells
beer"? What evidence in the article indicates success in these
efforts? What arguments might refute the fact that strategy change
accounts for this improvement?
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
"Unease Brewing at Anheuser As New Owners
Slash Costs," by David Kesmodel and Suzanne Vranica, The Wall Street
Journal, April 29, 2009 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124096182942565947.html?mod=djem_jiewr_AC
Construction crews
arrived at One Busch Place a few months ago and demolished the ornate
executive suites at Anheuser-Busch Cos. In their place the workers built
a sea of desks, where executives and others now work a few feet apart.
It is just one piece of
a sweeping makeover of the iconic American brewer by InBev, the Belgian
company that bought Anheuser-Busch last fall. In about six months, InBev
has turned a family-led company that spared little expense into one that
is focused intently on cost-cutting and profit margins, while rethinking
the way it sells beer.
The new owner has cut
jobs, revamped the compensation system and dropped perks that had made
Anheuser-Busch workers the envy of others in St. Louis. Managers
accustomed to flying first class or on company planes now fly coach.
Freebies like tickets to St. Louis Cardinals games are suddenly scarce.
Suppliers haven't been
spared the knife. The combined company, Anheuser-Busch InBev NV, has
told barley merchants, ad agencies and other vendors that it wants to
take up to 120 days to pay bills. The brewer of Budweiser, a company
with a rich history of memorable ads, has tossed out some sports deals
that were central to marketing at the old Anheuser-Busch.
The changes have been
tough for workers to swallow. Some are grappling with heavier workloads,
anxious about job security and frustrated with the emphasis on
penny-pinching, say people close to the brewer. Former executives say
workers feel less appreciated in a no-frills culture with fewer perks.
InBev's response: It's
more effective to make "sweeping, dramatic changes" than incremental
ones, said a spokeswoman for the Belgian company, which has a history of
many past mergers and acquisitions. Asked if morale in the U.S. is
suffering, Dave Peacock, a 40-year-old Anheuser-Busch veteran who heads
the U.S. division, said, "I think there's probably some truth....Some
people react very well, some people struggle with it." Returning to the
issue later in an interview, he said the newly merged company "is like a
start-up....That excites some people and turns off others."
It isn't yet clear how
well the megadeal will pan out. The combination created the world's
largest brewer by sales. But the tumult could offer an opening for
MillerCoors LLC, which is exhorting its people to exploit the transition
by trying to grab more shelf space at large retailers.
Anheuser-Busch has
nearly half of the U.S. beer market. It got a stronger challenger last
summer, however, when SABMiller PLC and Molson Coors Brewing Co. linked
their U.S. divisions in the joint venture called MillerCoors, with 29%
of the U.S. market. "The next chapter in American beer is being
written," MillerCoors President Tom Long said at a conference last
month.
Market-Share Gain But it
was Anheuser-Busch InBev that logged a market-share gain the first
quarter of this year, an increase of about three-quarters of a
percentage point at sales at retail stores excluding Wal-Mart Stores
Inc. The figures, from Information Resources Inc., show Anheuser-Busch
InBev lifting its U.S. beer sales 5.7% in dollar terms from a year
earlier. Bars and restaurants aren't included.
The U.S. market is
holding up well despite the recession, Anheuser-Busch InBev Chief
Executive Carlos Brito said Tuesday. "In tough times, it's a great
market to be exposed to," Mr. Brito, 48, said at a news conference after
the company's annual meeting in Brussels. He declined to be interviewed
for this article.
InBev emerged as a beer
heavyweight five years ago through the linkup of Brazil's AmBev, known
for Brahma beer, and the Belgian producer of Stella Artois, Interbrew
SA. Though it was based in Leuven, Belgium, the Brazilians' culture came
to dominate. That approach stresses a sharp eye on costs and
incentive-based pay structures.
InBev eschews fancy
offices and company cars, and groups of its executives share a single
secretary. It uses zero-based budgeting -- meaning all expenses must be
justified each year, not just increases. The company says it saved
€250,000 ($325,000) by telling employees in the U.K. to use double-sided
black-and-white printing, spending the money to hire more salespeople.
"We always say, the
leaner the business, the more money we'll have at the end of the year to
share," Mr. Brito, the CEO, said in a speech last year to students at
his alma mater, Stanford University business school.
Anheuser-Busch took a
different path, spending amply on everything from top beer ingredients
to the best hotel accommodations. Executives didn't just have
secretaries -- many also had executive assistants, who traveled with
their bosses, took notes and learned the business in a kind of
apprenticeship.
Most employees, even
those at the company's Sea World and Busch Gardens theme parks, got free
beer. Once the owner of the St. Louis Cardinals, the company continued
to shell out heavily for tickets to Cardinals games, used in marketing.
Employees who wanted the company to donate beer or merchandise for
community events faced little red tape. The St. Louis company often made
"best places to work" lists.
Heavy ad spending on
sports events, often as the exclusive beer advertiser, helped
Anheuser-Busch become the U.S.'s dominant brewer. But its growth and
stock performance turned sluggish in recent years as U.S. sales of
imports and small-batch "craft" beers rose faster than the St. Louis
giant's brands.
After InBev swooped in
last fall with a $52 billion takeover, it sacked about 1,400 employees
in the U.S., equal to 6% of the U.S. work force before the merger, and
415 contractor positions. These followed 1,000 employee buyouts accepted
at Anheuser-Busch just before the merger.
InBev has overhauled the
U.S. division's compensation system for salaried employees, as part of
what an internal memo called "an increased focus on meritocracy." In the
future, the company will pay salaried workers 80% to 100% of the market
rate for comparable jobs, "and any increases above that require special
justification and approvals," said the memo. That changed a system in
which "high performers...might have seen fewer rewards as dollars were
spread more evenly."
Continued in article
Questions
Complicated Math by Design: Derivative Instruments Fraud in the 1990s
and Executive Compensation in the 21st Century
Before derivative financial instruments were well understood by buyers,
sellers of such instruments like Merrill Lynch and many other top investment
banking firms on Wall Street became fraudulent bucket shops selling
derivatives packages that were so needlessly mathematical and complicated
that they intentionally deceived buyers like pension and trust fund
managers, When buyers commenced to lose millions upon millions of dollars,
the SEC commenced to investigate one of the more serious set of scandals to
ever hit wall street ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm#DerivativesFrauds
If you want to cry and laugh at the same time watch this expert (John Grant)
try to understand a derivatives contract sold by Merrill Lynch to Orange
County in California that eventually cost the County over a billion dollars
(and forced it into bankruptcy.
The video is an excerpt from a CBS Sixty Minute 1990sprogram (slow
loading) ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/acct5341/Calgary/CDfiles/video\FAS133/SIXTY01.avi
The point is that the investment banking firms in those days built in
complicated mathematics to deceive investors regarding the risk in the
investments these bankers were trying to sell in the 1990s. And it worked!
Investors lost millions.
In a similar manner in the 21st Century executives are trying
to circumvent the SEC's new compensation disclosure rules by making the
compensation contracts so complicated that nobody could comprehend what is
being disclosed.
"(New Math) x (SEC Rules) + Proxy=Confusion Firms Disclose Formulas
Behind Executive Pay, Leaving Many Baffled," by Phred Dvorak, The
Wall Street Journal, March 21, 2008; Page A1 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB120604424097452677.html?mod=todays_us_page_one
(but not quite as complicated as the investment banking formulas for fraud
in derivatives instruments selling)
The latest proxy statement from Applied
Materials Inc. tells exactly how the company set 2007 bonuses for top
executives:
"Base Salary x Individual Target Percentage x
(Weighted Score + Total Stockholder Return Adder, if Achieved)."
Of some help may be Applied's definition of
weighted score:
"(Performance Measure 1 x Weight as Percentage)
+ (Performance Measure 2 x Weight as Percentage)."
And so on.
As a maker of semiconductor equipment, Applied
Materials belongs to an industry of mathematical whizzes. Yet the
complexity of its proxy this year reflects a trend that extends far
beyond Silicon Valley. Even Deere & Co., the maker of tractors, has
produced a proxy that uses three formulas, four tables and a graph to
illustrate the calculation of executive bonuses.
This explosion of mathematics was sparked by
the Securities and Exchange Commission, which in 2006 began requiring
more information about how companies calculate executive pay. After the
first batch of proxies using the new rules arrived last year, the SEC
told 350 companies they hadn't been specific enough.
Among those companies was Applied Materials. So
this year, it expanded by 76% the word count of its proxy's compensation
section. In all, the compensation section contains 16,245 words -- twice
the length of the U.S. Constitution and its 27 Amendments -- along with
10 formulas, 10 tables and 155 percent signs.
The result, according to some experts, is
unfathomable. "Can even the executives figure out what they have to do
to get these awards?" asks Carol Bowie, head of corporate-governance
research at RiskMetrics Group Inc., which helps investors sort through
such filings.
The SEC has said that it wants disclosure to be
clear and concise, as well as comprehensive. But striking that balance
is difficult, companies say. So, many are erring on the side of detail.
"Bonus multiple x target bonus x base salary
earnings = payout," explains the new proxy from drug maker Eli Lilly &
Co., which last year received a letter from the SEC calling its
executive-pay disclosure inadequate. Just in case that term "bonus
multiple" isn't clear, the proxy explains that it is "(0.25 x sales
multiple) + (0.75 x adjusted EPS multiple)." To find the sales and EPS
multiples, investors must consult graphs.
Some firms may be throwing up their hands and
deluging the public with figures. "I know a couple of companies where
the frustration level with the SEC was so large that they said, 'Just
put it all in,'" says John A. Hill, a trustee at mutual-fund giant
Putnam Funds. Mr. Hill often chats about pay practices with officials of
companies whose stock Putnam investors own.
An SEC spokesman says it's too early to comment
on 2008 proxies.
Even activist investors who pushed for more
disclosure on executive pay are scratching their heads. "There have been
some proxies when I've gone through and said, 'Wow, I have no idea what
I just read,'" says Scott Zdrazil, director of corporate governance at
union-owned Amalgamated Bank, which manages around $12 billion in
pension-fund assets.
The Smell Test
Mr. Zdrazil says he uses a "smell test" to
judge whether companies are trying to obscure poor pay practices with
lots of detail, or just being wonky. "If you can clearly understand the
algebra involved, it passes," he says.
One that doesn't pass his test is software
maker Novell Inc. Its proxy tosses around such terms as "assigned
weighted quantitative performance objective achievement percentage," and
describes a two-step process for calculating executive bonuses:
First: "Bonus Funding Percentage x Weighted
Quantitative Performance Objectives Achievement x Qualitative
Performance Factor = Performance Factor."
Then: "Performance Factor x Target Bonus
Percentage x Base Salary = Recommended Bonus Amount."
Mr. Zdrazil says Novell fails to explain how
difficult it is for executives to achieve performance targets.
Asked about the formulas, Novell says it gave
more detail in response to the SEC's push and that its proxy statement
complies with SEC rules.
At first glance, the bonus formula at software
maker Adobe Systems Inc. seems straightforward: "Target Bonus x Unit
Multiplier x Individual Results."
But then comes the definition of unit
multiplier. Adobe says it is:
"Derived from aggregating the target bonus of
all participants in the Executive Bonus Plan multiplied by the funding
level determined under the funding matrix, and allocating a portion of
the funding level to each business or functional unit of Adobe based on
that unit's relative contribution to Adobe's success, and then dividing
the allocated funding level by the aggregate target bonuses of
participants working within each such unit." Got that?
After all that calculating, Adobe's top five
executives somehow received the exact same unit multiplier -- 200%.
Adobe says that was the highest possible percentage and that it reflects
how well the company performed.
Degree of Transparency
Adobe also says it "strives for a high degree
of transparency" in financial reporting, and that it added detail this
year on executive compensation "in that spirit, and in response to new
SEC requirements."
Applied's bonus formula was created a decade
ago by an employee who majored in math, but the company hadn't
previously included it in its filings. General Counsel Joe Sweeney says
the new compensation discussion has won praise from investors and
lawyers. Proxy adviser Glass Lewis & Co., which says it has no financial
relationship with Applied, called the company's proxy "clear and
concise."
But Applied shareholder Robert Friedman, a
retired computer programmer, isn't so sure. "This is too much," he says,
munching on a cookie and flipping through a proxy moments before the
company's March 11 annual meeting. "I own about a dozen companies, and
if I did this for every company..."
For all its length, Applied's proxy doesn't
reveal some crucial information, such as the target to which the company
would like to see its market share increase. That number -- key to
calculating the CEO's bonus according to the formula -- must be kept
from rivals, Mr. Sweeney, the general counsel, says. For the same
reason, the document also excludes some information about other
executives' performance goals. "I hate to think how long the
[compensation section] would have been if we had included all the
factors for all the individuals," says Mr. Sweeney.
So if some important factors remain secret,
what's the point of all the math? Mr. Sweeney says it is meant to give
shareholders a taste of the decision-making process.
CEOs are rewarded hundreds of millions of dollars even when they fail.
This is not competitive capitalism!
"Stanley O'Neal who is leaving Merrill Lynch
after giving it a big fat gift of a $8 billion dollar write-off thanks to
risky investments. The board just can't help but feed this obesity epidemic.
They're giving him $160 million plus in severance for his troubles as he
heads for the door. At some point, the nation's corporations, or most
pointedly, their corporate boards, will realize throwing money at their CEOs
is probably not the best idea"
"Obesity Epidemic Among CEO Pay," The Huffington Post, November 1, 2007 ---
http://www.huffingtonpost.com/eve-tahmincioglu/obesity-epidemic-among-ce_b_70810.html
From The Wall Street Journal Accounting Weekly Review on April 27,
2007
"House Clears an Executive-Pay Measure," by Kara Scannell,
The Wall Street Journal, April 21, 2007 Page: A3 ---
TOPICS: Accounting, Disclosure, Disclosure Requirements, Regulation,
Securities and Exchange Commission
SUMMARY: This article reports on legislation passed by a 269-134 margin
in the House to give "...shareholders a nonbinding vote on executive pay
packages and a separate vote on any compensation negotiated as part of a
purchase or sale of a company..." (a golden parachute). The legislation
"would require the Securities and Exchange Commission to write rules under
which investors could use company-issued ballot forms to vote on executive
pay on an advisory basis, starting in 2009." This legislation builds on a
law passed last year requiring greater disclosure about executive
compensation, including a total compensation figure--an item difficult to
determine from previous corporate financial statements. Business and the
White House generally disagree with the legislation, in part because of
fears that labor union negotiations would result in pay determinations based
on inequality issues rather than performance ones. A related article
identifies further specifics on the SEC's role in resolving these and other
hot issues.
QUESTIONS:
1.) Summarize the legislation passed by the House. What will be the next
step in attempts to pass this legislation? How would it be implemented?
2.) Does this legislation show any impact from the political process on
financial reporting practices? In your answer, consider also the general
process undertaken by the SEC to resolve "hot" issues as well.
3.) If the shareholders vote on the issues discussed in this article are
not binding under the law if it is ultimately passed and implemented, then
how would the law change current practices in executive compensation?
4.) Despite President Bush's comments on executive compensation in this
year's State of the Union address, administrators in the White House now say
they do not support the proposed law but prefer to allow time for recently
enacted reforms to take effect. What are these reforms? When were they
implemented?
5.) Focus in particular on the disclosure of executive pay packages in
answer to question 4. How might these disclosure requirements work to change
current practices in executive compensation?
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
RELATED ARTICLES: The SEC's Mr. Consensus by Kara Scannell, The Wall
Street Journal, Apr 20, 2007 Page: C1
From The Wall Street Journal Accounting Weekly Review on February
1, 2008
SEC Unhappy with Answers on Executive Pay
by
Kara Scannell and JoAnn S. Lublin
The Wall Street Journal
Jan 29, 2008
Page: B1
Click here to view the full article on WSJ.com ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB120156732373223843.html?mod=djem_jiewr_ac
TOPICS: Accounting,
Disclosure, Disclosure Requirements, Executive
compensation, SEC, Securities and Exchange Commission,
Stock Options
SUMMARY: During summer and fall 2007, the SEC sent
letters to 350 companies regarding the way in which they
make financial disclosures about top executive pay. The
SEC has reviewed the disclosures as "...part of its
effort to bring more information about executive pay to
shareholders after years of high-profile pay packages
and perquisites that many view as excessive. Shareholder
advocates are also pressing hard to give shareholders a
greater say in executive pay." Of particular concern is
the role of individual performance in Boards of
Directors pay decisions about chief executives. As a
result, some practitioners and academics think that
companies may switch to using performance targets that
they prefer to disclose. The article focuses on SEC
interaction with Bristol-Myers Squibb.
CLASSROOM APPLICATION: Issues surrounding disclosure
of executive pay packages can be discussed in MBA
courses on financial reporting, prior to coverage of
stock compensation accounting in intermediate and
advanced accounting courses, and other ways.
QUESTIONS:
1.) Based on discussion in the article, what are the
current difficulties with disclosures regarding
executive compensation?
2.) Based on discussion in the related article, what SEC
disclosure requirements for executive compensation were
recently established?
3.) Consider the requirement to describe performance
targets that form the basis for executive compensation.
Why are investors interested in that information? What
information does it provide beyond presentation of
annual executive compensation in historical cost based
financial statements? In your answer, address comments
from Baxter International's corporate secretary and
associate general counsel, David P. Scharf, and quoted
in the article.
4.) Consider the opinion, held by some, that companies
might prefer not to disclose performance targets and
therefore change the measures by which their Boards
assess executive compensation. Why might disclosure of
these targets cause competitive harm? Should competitive
harm be considered in the SEC's assessment of the
disclosures it requires? Support your answer.
5.) From where did the authors obtain the data about SEC
letters that is included in this article? In your
answer, specifically examine data for one of the
companies referenced in the article that is available
through the SEC's web site.
6.) What is a proxy statement? Describe the compensation
disclosures given by one of the companies referenced in
the article in its 2006 proxy statement.
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
RELATED ARTICLES:
SEC Asks Firms to Detail Top Executives' Pay
by Kara Scannell and JoAnn S. Lublin
Aug 31, 2007
Page: B1
|
"SEC Unhappy With Answers on Executive Pay," by Kara Scannell and Joann
S. Lublin, The Wall Street Journal, January 29, 2008; Page B1 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB120156732373223843.html?mod=djem_jiewr_ac
The Securities and Exchange Commission sent
letters to 350 companies last summer and fall critiquing the way they
described the pay of their top executives. But the federal watchdog
isn't happy with most of the answers it got.
A majority of the companies have now received
second letters, according to an SEC official, and of 26 companies whose
cases were closed, 21 were chided for not giving enough information
about the role of individual performance in their pay decisions.
In writing to one of them, Bristol-Myers Squibb
Co., the SEC noted that individual performance "was a primary
determinate of compensation" but that the New York drug maker didn't
properly describe how that measure translated to the pay it handed out.
Sandra Leung, Bristol-Myers's general counsel
and corporate secretary, promised to do better in the future -- in so
many words. In an Oct. 10 letter, she said Bristol-Myers will elaborate
in future filings "on the manner in which the named executive officers'
performance against individual financial and operational
objectives...impacted their resultant compensation." And Robert Zito, a
Bristol-Myers spokesman, added that this year's proxy statement "will
certainly be prepared consistent with our response to the SEC comment
letter."
The increasing SEC scrutiny could spur changes
in how companies calculate compensation, including moving away from
individual performance as a measure of success -- one of the areas the
SEC focused on as particularly weak -- in favor of companywide financial
targets, such as earnings or stock prices.
"Quantifying individual performance targets
isn't the easiest thing to do," said James D.C. Barrall, a Los Angeles
attorney and executive-pay specialist at Latham & Watkins LLP, who
expects to see such a shift.
The companies most likely to change would be
those that use performance targets they'd prefer to keep confidential,
such as return on capital, said Ronald Mueller, a compensation expert at
the law firm Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher in Washington, D.C. "In my
experience, some companies switched to performance targets that they
would be more comfortable disclosing," he said.
Another possible result is that companies will
stuff even more information into company proxy statements, which are
already larded with charts and footnotes. That could mean an additional
table with top officers' individual goals and how their pay stacks up
against colleagues' rewards. Scott Olsen, head of the rewards practice
at PricewaterhouseCoopers in New York, says a lot of people think that's
what "the SEC is looking for."
The scrutiny could have the unintended
consequence of pushing companies to focus on short-term measures such as
earnings or stock prices, which, critics say, can distort how companies
are managed. An obsession with stock prices was one factor in the raft
of corporate frauds that accompanied the end of the dot.com boom. Last
year a panel organized by the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, the nation's
largest business lobby, recommended that CEOs stop giving quarterly
earnings guidance as part of a push to refocus on long-term results.
The review by the SEC is part of its effort to
bring more information about executive pay to shareholders after years
of high-profile pay packages and perquisites that many view as
excessive. Shareholder advocates are also pressing hard to give
shareholders a greater say in executive pay.
Letters from the 26 completed cases were
recently made public on the SEC's Web site. The others will be posted 45
days after the SEC considers itself satisfied.
In response, Mr. Tobin wrote on Nov. 9 that his
"limited" raise reflected that "the company had only achieved quarterly
sales and earnings targets in two of four quarters in 2005, Taxus market
share lagged expectations and the launch of Taxus in Japan had been
delayed." The company didn't state the specific quarterly targets.
Spokesmen for Baxter International Inc., DuPont
Co., Safeway Inc. and Electronic Data Systems Corp. -- other recipients
of SEC letters -- said it is too early to offer details beyond their
response letters because they're still discussing possible changes with
directors or preparing their 2008 proxy statements.
"We are just now completing financial reporting
and analysis for the year and are evaluating performance and potential
compensation decisions with our board," said a spokeswoman for Baxter, a
health-products concern in Deerfield, Ill.
David P. Scharf, Baxter's corporate secretary
and associate general counsel, wrote that there were limits on what he
was willing to tell the SEC.
In his Oct. 22 response, he said additional
information will be limited by the company's desire to avoid disclosing
confidential information about unquantifiable "qualitative elements" of
each top officer's pay. In any case, he continued, such revelations
would not provide "substantial value to investors in understanding our
compensation policies and decisions."
Where were the auditors?
Firms cook the books to set executive pay
And these same executives are protesting Sarbanes-Oxley
"Firms cook the books to set executive pay," Editorial, The New York
Times, December 19, 23006 ---
http://www.sptimes.com/2006/12/19/Opinion/Firms_cook_the_books_.shtml
Among the corporate deceits that buttress
America's obscene executive pay is the one about comparability. But a
new federal rule may help expose the reality of so-called "peer groups."
Far too often, the list of comparable CEOs is cooked.
As the New York Times reported in its latest
installment on executive pay, former New York Stock Exchange chairman
Richard Grasso was a poster child for the abuse. His $140-million
compensation package was rationalized, in part, by comparing his job to
those at companies with median revenues 25 times the size of the
exchange, assets 125 times and employee bases 30 times the size.
Grasso was hardly alone. Executives have
learned that the path to personal riches is paved by "peer groups" that
include big and profitable companies. Eli Lilly compared itself to eight
companies that had much higher profit margins. Campbell Soup used one
set of companies for executive pay and a separate one as a benchmark for
stock performance. Ford Motor Co. compared itself to other industries,
its proxy statement said, because "the job market for executives goes
beyond the auto industry."
The "job market" argument is particularly
disingenuous. As the New York Times noted, ousted Hewlett-Packard chief
executive Carly Fiorina was replaced by a data processing executive who
was earning less than half her pay. His company, NCR, never appeared on
the Hewlett-Packard "peer group."
The growth in executive pay has been so
meteoric in the past quarter-century that it is demeaning the
contributions of average workers and undermining public faith in
corporate America. Last year, according to the Corporate Library, the
average pay for an S&P 500 chief executive was $13.5-million. The
average CEO now earns 411 times the average worker, up from 42 times in
1980.
The new Securities and Exchange Commission
disclosure rules went into effect on Friday, and compensation
consultants are scrambling to cover their tracks. But stockholders who
have been kept mostly in the dark will now at least have a chance to see
the playbook. That's the first step toward ending these games of
executive greed.
Bob Jensen's fraud updates are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudUpdates.htm
Bob Jensen's threads on fraudulent and incompetent auditing are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#IncompetentAudits
Four Banks Charged in Parmalat Failure
A Milan judge has ordered Citigroup, UBS, Morgan
Stanley and Deutsche Bank to stand trial for market-rigging in connection
with dairy firm Parmalat's collapse, judicial sources said. Judge Cesare
Tacconi also ordered 13 individuals to face trial on the same charges, at
the end of preliminary hearings into the case, the sources told Reuters on
Wednesday.
Reuters, June 13, 2007 ---
Click Here
Parmalat's external auditor was Grant Thornton ---
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#GrantThornton
Yahoo Shareholders View Executive Pay as Excessive
I.S.S., along with Glass Lewis and Proxy
Governance, criticized the compensation committee for awarding bonus and
retention pay in the form of 6.8 million stock options to Terry S. Semel,
Yahoo’s chief executive, in a year when the company’s shares dropped nearly
35 percent. I.S.S. valued Mr. Semel’s pay in 2006 at $107.5 million, making
him one of the nation’s best-paid executives. Separately, Yahoo shareholders
rejected approximately 2-to-1 a proposal that would have tied executive
compensation to competitive performance. They also rejected, by wider
margins, proposals to establish a committee to oversee Yahoo’s human rights
practices and to require the company to fight censorship and protect freedom
of access to the Internet in countries with repressive regimes.
Miguel Helft, "Dissident Shareholders Send Message to Yahoo," The
New York Times, June 13, 2007 ---
Click Here
How KB Home CEO's pay went through the roof
KB Home may be the fifth-largest U.S. home builder,
but it was No. 1 when it came to pay for its chief executive. Over the last
three years, former CEO Bruce Karatz made $232.6 million in compensation.
Kathy M. Kristof and Annette Haddad, LA Times, December 17, 2006 ---
http://www.latimes.com/services/site/premium/access-registered.intercept
Jensen Comment
I'd be more impressed if KB homes bought back the fundamentally-flawed
cracked foundations of all those defective homes built in Texas ---
http://ths.gardenweb.com/forums/load/build/msg0122380524478.html?12
Recall when "agency theory" assumed that CEO's had personal incentives to
make accounting transparent without the need for outside regulation
requirements? This is probably still being taught in accounting theory courses
where instructors rely on old textbooks and journal articles.
In the latest twist in the stock options game, some
executives may have changed the so-called exercise date — the date options can
be converted to stock — to avoid paying hundreds of thousands of dollars in
income tax, federal investigators say . . . As those cases have progressed, at
least 46 executives and directors have been ousted from their positions.
Companies have taken charges totaling $5.3 billion to account for the impact of
improper grants, according to Glass Lewis & Company, a research firm that
advises big investors on shareholder issues. And further investigations,
indictments and restatements are expected. Securities regulators are now
focusing on several cases where it appears the exercise dates of the options
were backdated, according to a senior S.E.C. enforcement official, who asked not
to be identified because of the agency’s policy of not commenting on active
cases. Besides raising disclosure and accounting problems, backdating an
exercise date can result in tax fraud.
Eric Dash, "Dodging Taxes Is a New Stock Options Scheme," The New York Times,
October 30, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/10/30/business/30option.html?_r=1&oref=slogin
You can read about agency theory at
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Agency_Theory
You can read the following at
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Agency_Theory#Incentive-Intensity_Principle
Incentive-Intensity Principle
However, setting incentives as intense as
possible is not necessarily optimal from the point of view of the
employer. The Incentive-Intensity Principle states that the optimal
intensity of incentives depends on four factors: the incremental profits
created by additional effort, the precision with which the desired
activities are assessed, the agent’s risk tolerance, and the agent’s
responsiveness to incentives. According to Prendergast (1999, 8), “the
primary constraint on [performance-related pay] is that [its] provision
imposes additional risk on workers…” A typical result of the early
principal-agent literature was that piece rates tend to 100% (of the
compensation package) as the worker becomes more able to handle risk, as
this ensures that workers fully internalize the consequences of their
costly actions. In incentive terms, where we conceive of workers as
self-interested rational individuals who provide costly effort (in the
most general sense of the worker’s input to the firm’s production
function), the more compensation varies with effort, the better the
incentives for the worker to produce.
Monitoring Intensity Principle
The third principle – the Monitoring Intensity
Principle – is complementary to the second, in that situations in which
the optimal intensity of incentives is high correspond to situations in
which the optimal level of monitoring is also high. Thus employers
effectively choose from a “menu” of monitoring/incentive intensities.
This is because monitoring is a costly means of reducing the variance of
employee performance, which makes more difference to profits in the
kinds of situations where it is also optimal to make incentives intense.
Bob Jensen's threads on earnings management and agency theory are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen//theory/00overview/theory01.htm#Manipulation
Corrupt Corporate Governance
For years, the health insurer didn't tell investors
about personal and financial links between its former CEO and the "independent"
director in charge of compensation
Jane Sasseen, "The Ties UnitedHealth Failed to Disclose: For years, the
health insurer didn’t tell investors about personal and financial links between
its former CEO and the "independent" director in charge of compensation,"
Business Week, October 18, 2006 ---
Click Here
"Gluttons At The Gate: Private equity are using slick new
tricks to gorge on corporate assets. A story of excess," by Emily Thornton,
Business Week Cover Story, October 30, 2006 ---
Click Here
Buyout firms have always been aggressive. But
an ethos of instant gratification has started to spread through the
business in ways that are only now coming into view. Firms are
extracting record dividends within months of buying companies, often
financed by loading them up with huge amounts of debt. Some are quietly
going back to the till over and over to collect an array of dubious
fees. Some are trying to flip their holdings back onto the public
markets faster than they've ever dared before. A few are using financial
engineering and bankruptcy proceedings to wrest control of companies. At
the extremes, the quick-money mindset is manifesting itself in possibly
illegal activity: Some private equity executives are being investigated
for outright fraud.
Taken together, these trends serve as a warning
that the private-equity business has entered a historic period of
excess. "It feels a lot like 1999 in venture capital," says Steven N.
Kaplan, finance professor at the University of Chicago. Indeed, it
shares elements of both the late-1990s VC craze, in which too much money
flooded into investment managers' hands, as well as the 1980s buyout
binge, in which swaggering dealmakers hunted bigger and bigger prey. But
the fast money--and the increasingly creative ways of getting it--set
this era apart. "The deal environment is as frothy as I've ever seen
it," says Michael Madden, managing partner of private equity firm
BlackEagle Partners Inc. "There are still opportunities to make good
returns, but you have to have a special angle to achieve them."
Like any feeding frenzy, this one began with
just a few nibbles. The stock market crash of 2000-02 sent corporate
valuations plummeting. Interest rates touched 40-year lows. With stocks
in disarray and little yield to be gleaned from bonds, big investors
such as pension funds and university endowments began putting more money
in private equity. The buyout firms, benefiting from the most generous
borrowing terms in memory, cranked up their dealmaking machines. They
also helped resuscitate the IPO market, bringing public companies that
were actually making money--a welcome change from the sketchy offerings
of the dot-com days. As the market recovered, those stocks bolted out of
the gate. And because buyout firms retain controlling stakes even after
an IPO, their results zoomed, too, as the stocks rose. Annual returns of
20% or more have been commonplace.
The success has lured more money into private
equity than ever before--a record $159 billion so far this year,
compared with $41 billion in all of 2003, estimates researcher Private
Equity Intelligence. The first $5 billion fund popped up in 1996; now,
Kohlberg Kravis Roberts, Blackstone Group, and Texas Pacific Group are
each raising $15 billion funds.
And that's the main problem: There's so much
money sloshing around that everyone wants a quick cut. "For the
management of the company, [a buyout is] usually a windfall," says Wall
Street veteran Felix G. Rohatyn, now a senior adviser at Lehman Brothers
Inc. (LEH ) "For the private equity firms with cheap money and a very
well structured fee schedule, it's a wonderful business. The risk is
ultimately in the margins they leave themselves to deal with bad times."
Continued in article
Insiders are still screwing the investing public
"Trading in Harrah's Contracts Surges Before LBO Disclosure: Options,
Derivatives Make Exceptionally Large Moves; 'Someone...Was Positioning'," by
Dennis K. Berman and Serena Ng, The Wall Street Journal, October 4, 2006;
Page C3 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article_print/SB115992145253481882.html
Bob Jensen's threads on "Corporate Governance" are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
Bob Jensen's "Rotten to the Core" threads are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm
Compensation Special Report, Parts I & II, CFO Magazine,
November 2006 ---
http://www.cfo.com/guides/guide.cfm/7932402?f
DIRECTOR & OFFICER COMPENSATION
A Farewell to Perks?
The SEC's new compensation-disclosure rules could mean the end of
luxurious wine cellars and questionable stipends.
IRS Chief: CFO Pay Should Be Fixed
At a Senate hearing, Internal Revenue Service Commissioner Mark Everson
says finance chiefs shouldn't be paid in options, and a ranking senator
seems itching to legislate.
Battle Lines Drawn on Executive Pay
A House bill would require shareholder approval for corporate
compensation policies.
Study: Director Pay Hikes Slowing Down
Further, fewer companies are making stock options a component of
directors' compensation packages, with 53 percent providing them 2005—
down from 59 percent in 2004 and 66 percent in 2003.
Directors Say Exec Pay Hurts Image
Two-thirds of board members also believe that the current model for
executive compensation has contributed to superior corporate
performance, according to a new survey; less than one-quarter of
institutional investors share that view. Executive Pay Prognosis:
Marginal Change The market for senior management pay is likely to keep
compensation up—even in the face of more disclosure. Survey Says Comp
Rules No Big Deal Even as multiple Senate hearings focus on executive
compensation, a survey of human resource professionals says new SEC
rules will have little impact on compensation or company performance.
EMPLOYEE COMPENSATION
Study: Talent Will Cost More
Hiring qualified employees could hit companies in the wallet in the
coming year.
State's Rights: Many Lift Minimum Wage
While Congress fiddles, the states are raising the minimum wage.
BACKDATING BLOWS UP
When Is Backdating a Crime?
The burden will be on DoJ prosecutors to prove Brocade executives
deliberately misled investors. Is Spring-loading Wrong? Testimony on
Capitol Hill today did nothing to resolve the ongoing debate over
whether spring-loading of stock options is illegal or unethical.
Backdating Blamed on 1993 Tax Rule Disturbed by the manipulation of
option grants, Congress is toying with eliminating the $1 million tax
cap on executive compensation.
"25 Reasons Employees Lie, Cheat, and Steal," SmartPros,
September 2006 ---
http://accounting.smartpros.com/x54052.xml
On-the-job theft goes beyond greed, according
to authorities in white-collar crime (criminologists, sociologists,
auditors, risk managers, etc.), who cite a large list of reasons for
employee theft.
In fact, a new edition of Fraud Auditing and
Forensic Accounting lists a long list of 25 reasons -- some of which
are common knowledge, but others may surprise. They include:
- The employee believes he can get away with
it.
- No one has ever been prosecuted for
stealing from the organization.
- Employees are not encouraged to discuss
personal or financial problems at work or to seek management's
advice and counsel on such matters.
Read the entire list and check out Book Corner
for more details on the book.
Bob Jensen's threads on theft and fraud are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud.htm
Question
What do companies and executives who back dated options fear the most?
The Internal Revenue Service is examining as
many as 40 companies ensnared in various stock options investigations to
determine whether they owe millions of dollars in unpaid taxes. In the last
few weeks, the agency has directed its corporate auditors to start reviewing
the tax returns of dozens of executives and companies, which may have
improperly reported stock option grants. These preliminary investigations
are expected to take months, but if there is early evidence of widespread
tax trouble, I.R.S. officials said they were prepared to step up their
effort. “Where there are indications of mischief, we want to now look at
those cases and see if they complied with tax laws,” said Bruce Ungar, the
agency’s deputy commissioner for large and midsize businesses. “It is
possible that they are compliant, but the early indication is that there is
a good likelihood there is some noncompliance.
Eric Dash, "I.R.S. Reviewing Companies in Options Inquiries," The New
York Times, July 28, 2006 ---
Click Here
Jensen Comment
The first 40 companies are only a drop in this scandalous bucket. Over 2,000
companies are suspected of this unethical compensation ploy.
It appears that thousands of CEOs were allowed by their boards to bet
on yesterday's horse race
In theory, directors are supposed to help keep
wayward practices like options backdating in check at most companies, but at
Mercury it was the directors themselves — who received a final seal of
approval from the company’s compensation committee — who kept the backdating
ball rolling. Now, as federal investigations of possible regulatory and
accounting violations related to options backdating have expanded to include
more than 80 companies. Mercury’s pay practices — and the actions of the
three outside directors on its compensation and audit committees — have come
under scrutiny. In late June, the Securities and Exchange Commission advised
the three men that it was considering filing a civil complaint against them
in connection with dozens of manipulated options grants.
Eric Dash, "Who Signed Off on Those Options?" The New York Times,
August 27, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/08/27/business/yourmoney/27mercury.html
Bob Jensen's threads on executive options compensation scandals are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/theory/sfas123/jensen01.htm
Executives Are Betting On Yesterday's Horse Races
As an aside, once again this shows
that finance and accounting go hand in hand as Collins, Gong,
and Li are accounting professors!
From Jim Mahar's blog on May 23, 2006 ---
http://financeprofessorblog.blogspot.com/
Do managers
backdate options?
Do managers backdate options? It
sure seems that way.
From
Reuters:
A U.S. government probe into
stock option grants for executives widened on
Tuesday with more technology companies being called
on to explain the way these grants are awarded.
The investigation focuses
on whether companies are giving executives backdated
options after a run-up in the stock. Backdated
securities are priced at a value before a rally,
which boosts their returns.
From
NPR:
The
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) is
reportedly examining the timing of stock option
awards by corporations." (BTW this is included to
you can listen to it--has several professors
speaking on it.)
From the
LA Times:
""The stock-option game is
supposed to confer the potential for profit, but
also some risk," said John Freeman, a professor of
business ethics at the University of South Carolina
Law School who was a special counsel to the SEC
during the 1970s. "When in essence the executives
are betting on yesterday's horse races, knowing the
outcome, there's no risk whatever.""
What does past academic
research have to say on this? Most of the evidence
suggests that backdating probably does occur.
For years there have been
papers showing that managers tend to announce bad news
prior to option grants and even time the grants prior to
price run ups (see Yermack 1997) it has only been more
recently that researchers have noticed that the price
appreciation was not merely due to firm specific factors
(which managers may be able to control and time) but
also market wide factors (i.e. the stock market goes up
after option grants).
Last year a paper by
Narayanan and Seyhun suggested
that this may be the result of backdating the option
grants. More recently two papers by Collins, Gong, and
Li (a)
and (b)
find further evidence that
backdating is (or at least was) happening and that
unscheduled grant dates (where this can occur) tend to
be found more commonly at firms whose management has
relatively more control over their board of directors.
Stay tuned!!
* A quick comment to any manager who may have done this:
Why bother? Why risk it all cheating for a few extra
dollars? (Indeed it reminds me of the Adelphia case
where the firm outsourced snow plowing to a Rigas owned
firm. It just doesn't seem worth it.)
*As an aside, once again this shows that finance and
accounting go hand in hand as Collins, Gong, and Li are
accounting professors!
Bob Jensen's threads on outrageous executive compensation
are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
Question
How excessive is executive compensation and what can be done about it?
From Jim Mahar's Blog on August 22, 2006 ---
http://financeprofessorblog.blogspot.com/
Are CEOs overpaid?
Yeah, I know I said I would go a while before
posting, but Rich forwarded this to me and I think many of you will
be interested. It is from
MSNBC/Newsweek:
A few look-ins:
*"Ogling executive pay is the spectator
sport of business. The catcalls from the stands have gotten
louder as new studies throw out eye-popping statistics about how
rich CEOs are getting, while the rest of us worry about keeping
our jobs out of China. One such: the U.S.-based Institute for
Policy Studies notes that CEOs made 142 times more than the
average worker in 1994—and 431 times more in 2004."
*"Democratic Congressman Barney Frank is proposing a Protection
Against Executive Compensation Abuse Act, which would limit tax
deductions for companies that pay executives more than 25 times
the lowest paid worker. But even as the drumbeat for reform
grows louder, some new research is questioning just how out of
proportion these megapackages really are—and whether more
regulation is the best way to scale them down.First,
there's the issue of metrics....[the article then shows that
using medians reduced the average CEO to average worker pay
mulltple to 187].
*Xavier
Gabaix of MIT and Augustin Landier of NYU
say that since 1980 the pay of CEOs has
risen in lock step with the market capitalization of their
companies: both are up 500 percent.
*"Good governance still plays some part in determining pay—the
researchers say that CEOs can garner 10 to 20 percent more by
going to a firm with a weak board. And cultural mores play some
role, too; many of the Japanese firms studied were as big as
American firms, but executives were paid less and changed jobs
less often."
*"...nearly all firms are moving toward heavier reliance on
bonuses. The average dollar amount of bonuses has doubled in the
last three years, as they make up a growing proportion of
pay...."
Interesting article and an easy read so it
is perfect for the final "lazy, hazy, crazy days of summer."
Bob Jensen's threads on outrageous executive compensation are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudConclusion.htm#OutrageousCompensation
"Overpaid Management: Their Cover Is Blown," by Mark
Maisonneuve, The Wall Street Journal, June 22, 2006; Page A17 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB115094549688587219.html?mod=todays_us_opinion
Jeremy Siegel ("The
'Noisy Market' Hypothesis," editorial page,
June 14) blithely blames advisers for advocating capitalization-weighted
indexes when in fact academics were the drivers. While individual
advisers can move their small set of clients in any direction, academics
have to consider that their research would apply to everyone. By
definition everyone constitutes the total market and the total market
can be held only on a cap-weighted basis.
But he redeems himself with the
noisy market hypothesis, though in a way he might not have considered.
With one blow we are rid of the justification for CEO pay bloat on the
basis that the shareholders have been rewarded with a higher stock
price. Noisy markets imply that the higher price may only be a chimera
of temporary overvaluation. To Prof. Siegel's factors of
diversification, liquidity and taxes I would add financial manipulation
by the group most rewarded by overvaluation -- stock-option-laden senior
management. Now that their cover is blown, shareholders and their boards
can work to ensure that high pay is earned by real gains in fundamental
value.
"The Winding Road to Grasso's Huge Payday," by Landon Thomas,
The New York Times, June 25, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/06/25/business/yourmoney/25grasso.html
In the spring of 2003, the chairman of the New
York Stock Exchange, Richard A. Grasso, had his eyes on a very rich
prize. Although Mr. Grasso's annual compensation at the time was about
$12 million, on a par with the salaries of Wall Street titans whose
companies the exchange helped regulate, he had accumulated $140 million
in pension savings that he wanted to cash in — while still staying on
the job.
Now Henry M. Paulson Jr., the chairman of
Goldman Sachs and a member of the exchange's compensation committee, was
grilling Mr. Grasso about the propriety of drawing down such an enormous
amount and suggested that he seek legal advice. So Mr. Grasso said he
would call Martin Lipton, a veteran Manhattan lawyer and the Big Board's
chief counsel on governance matters. Would it be legal, Mr. Grasso
subsequently asked Mr. Lipton, to just withdraw the $140 million if the
exchange's board approved it? Mr. Grasso told Mr. Lipton that he worried
that a less accommodating board might not support such a move, according
to an account of the conversation that Mr. Lipton recently provided to
New York State prosecutors. (Mr. Grasso has denied voicing that
concern.) Mr. Lipton said he told Mr. Grasso not to worry; as long as
directors used their best judgment, Mr. Grasso's request was
appropriate.
Mr. Grasso continued to fret. What about
possible public distaste for the move? Yes, there would be some
resistance from corporate governance activists, Mr. Lipton recalled
telling him, but given his unique standing in the business community he
was "fully deserving of the compensation."
Then Mr. Lipton, a founding partner of Wachtell
Lipton Rosen & Katz and a longtime adviser to chief executives on the
hot seat, dangled another, hardball option in front of Mr. Grasso. If a
new board resisted a payout, Mr. Lipton advised, Mr. Grasso could just
sue the board to get his $140 million. The conversation represented a
pivotal moment at the exchange, occurring when corporate governance and
executive compensation were already areas of public concern. Mr. Grasso
eventually secured his pension funds. But the particulars surrounding
the payout later spurred Mr. Paulson to organize a highly publicized
palace revolt against Mr. Grasso, leading to the Big Board's most
glaring crisis since Richard Whitney, a previous president, went to jail
on embezzlement charges in 1938.
An examination of thousands of pages of
depositions from participants in the Big Board drama, as well as other
recent court filings, highlights the financial spoils available to those
in Wall Street's top tier. It also shines a light on deeply flawed
governance practices and clashing egos at one of America's most august
financial institutions, all of which came into sharp relief as Mr.
Grasso jockeyed to secure his $140 million.
ELIOT SPITZER, the New York State attorney
general, sued Mr. Grasso in 2004, contending that his Big Board
compensation was "unreasonable" and a violation of New York's
not-for-profit laws. With a trial looming this fall, prosecutors have
closely questioned both Mr. Lipton and Mr. Grasso about their phone
call. Prosecutors are likely to highlight Mr. Grasso's own doubts about
the propriety of cashing in his pension; on two separate occasions Mr.
Grasso withdrew his pension proposal from board consideration before
finally going ahead with it.
The depositions paint a portrait of Mr. Grasso
as a man who paid meticulous attention to every financial perk, from
items like flowers and 99-cent bags of pretzels that he billed to the
exchange, to his stubborn determination to corral his $140 million nest
egg. While the board ultimately approved his deal, court documents also
show a roster of all-star directors, including chief executives of all
the major Wall Street firms, often at odds with one another or acting
dysfunctionally.
A recent filing by Mr. Spitzer contended that
Mr. Grasso's chief advocate, Kenneth G. Langone, a longtime friend and
chairman of the Big Board's compensation committee, was less than
forthcoming in keeping the exchange's 26-member board in the loop about
how Mr. Grasso's rising pay was also inflating his retirement savings.
Continued in article
Bob Jensen's fraud updates are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudUpdates.htm
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate governance are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
Bob Jensen's "Rotten to the Core" threads are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm
As Workers' Pensions Wither, Those for Executives Flourish
This is the pension squeeze companies aren't
talking about: Even as many reduce, freeze or eliminate pensions for workers
-- complaining of the costs -- their executives are building up ever-bigger
pensions, causing the companies' financial obligations for them to balloon.
Ellen E. Schultz and Theo Francis, "As Workers' Pensions Wither, Those for
Executives Flourish: Companies Run Up Big IOUs, Mostly Obscured, to
Grant Bosses a Lucrative Benefit The Billion-Dollar Liability," The Wall
Street Journal, June 23, 2006; Page A1 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB115103062578188438.html?mod=todays_us_page_one
Outrageous Executive Audacity
"That Other Guy From Omaha," by Gretchen Morgenson, The New York Times,
August 29, 2006
Mr. Gupta is, shall we say, a piece of work. He
often prevents large shareholders from asking questions on conference
calls. He has received compensation that was not earned under the terms
of the company’s executive compensation program, according to a lawsuit
that Cardinal Value Equity Partners, infoUSA’s largest outside holder,
filed against the company. And, the suit alleges, his board has given
him free rein to dispense stock options to whomever he likes.
Related-party transactions are also routine at
infoUSA. The Cardinal lawsuit contends that infoUSA paid a company owned
by Mr. Gupta about $608,000 in 2003 to buy his interest in a skybox at
the University of Nebraska’s Memorial Stadium. The university is Mr.
Gupta’s alma mater and home of the Cornhuskers football team. In June
2005, the suit says, infoUSA paid $2.2 million for a long-term lease of
his yacht. The yacht, named American Princess, is 80 feet long and has
an all-female crew, according to a report in The Triton, a monthly
publication for boat captains and crews.
Leases on an H2 Hummer, a gold Honda Odyssey, a
Glacier Bay Catamaran, a Mini Cooper, a Lexus 330, a Mercedes SL500
all used by the Gupta clan as well as rent on a Gupta family
condominium on Maui have also been financed by infoUSA shareholders, the
suit said.
Shareholders also paid a company owned by Mr.
Gupta’s wife $64,200 for consulting services in 2003 and 2004.
Shareholders have also covered the Gupta family’s personal use of a
corporate jet leased by infoUSA from a company owned by the family
to have fun in the sun in Hawaii and the Bahamas. Mr. Gupta apparently
wasn’t in a mood to return the favor: during a four-year period ending
in 2004, infoUSA paid $13.5 million to Mr. Gupta’s private company for
use of the aircraft.
What to make of all of this? The Cardinal
lawsuit contends that the carnivalesque spending amounts to unregulated
perquisites and evidence of a somnambulant board. Sleepy, perhaps, but
always on the move. Some 15 directors have spun through infoUSA’s
boardroom door over the last decade; five of them stayed less than a
year.
It wasn’t until two years ago November 2004
that infoUSA’s board created guidelines for the approval of
related-party transactions over $60,000. The Cardinal lawsuit alleges
that some of infoUSA’s related-party dealings with certain board members
“did not have a sufficient record to show authorizations and whether the
services could be procured from other sources at comparable prices.”
None of the infoUSA board members returned
phone calls seeking comment. Mr. Gupta did not return several phone
calls, either.
But Mr. Gupta’s biggest faux pas occurred in
June 2005, when infoUSA warned that its earnings would not be up to
expectations. The stock fell from $11.94 a share to $9.85 the day after
the announcement. Less than a week later, Mr. Gupta offered to acquire
infoUSA for $11.75 a share, far less than the $18 a share he had said
the company was worth just a few months earlier.
A special committee of the company’s board was
set up to evaluate Mr. Gupta’s offer and to field bids from other
possible partners in order to secure the highest possible price for
infoUSA shareholders. Almost exactly a year ago, the committee concluded
that the $11.75 offer was too low and that it should be subject to a
“market check.”
At a board meeting on Aug. 26, 2005, Mr. Gupta
said that he would not sell any of his shares to a third party in an
alternative transaction, according to the lawsuit. Some directors might
have used this opportunity to give Mr. Gupta a well-earned public
rebuke. But a majority of the sleepwalkers at infoUSA just got into
lockstep with their chief executive.
The directors responded by deciding that there
was no need for infoUSA’s special committee to exist. They voted 5 to 3
(with one abstention) to abolish it. The only directors voting for the
committee’s continuance were three of its four members; the fourth
abstained from voting. The stock closed that day at $10.89.
The vote was the last straw for Cardinal Value
Equity Partners. It filed suit in February against Mr. Gupta, some of
infoUSA’s directors and the company itself.
“Our suit says that the special committee was
prematurely terminated, that they didn’t get to finish their work and
that was the wrong decision by the entire board,” said Robert B.
Kirkpatrick, a managing director at Cardinal Capital Management. “We’re
not asking for $100 billion; we ask that the special committee be
reconstituted to be able to have the time to fulfill their original
mandate as dictated by the board.”
In other words, to reopen the possibility of a
buyout.
IN the meantime, all is right in Mr. Gupta’s
gilded world. About three weeks ago, on Aug. 4, infoUSA announced that
it was buying Opinion Research, a consulting services company, for $12 a
share, an almost 100 percent premium to Opinion Research’s market price
the day before the announcement.
Lo and behold, who owned Opinion Research
shares the day the deal was announced? The Vinod Gupta Revocable Trust,
according to a regulatory filing, owned 33,000 shares. The trust,
controlled by Mr. Gupta, sold 22,000 of its shares after the merger
announcement sent Opinion Research’s stock rocketing.
The trust’s shares don’t represent a huge
stake, but it is worth asking: Did infoUSA’s directors know that the
Gupta trust was an Opinion Research shareholder when they signed off on
the premium-priced deal? And what gains did the trust record when it
sold into the deal-jazzed market? For now, the answers are unclear.
In coming weeks, a judge in Delaware will rule
on whether the Cardinal lawsuit can proceed. InfoUSA has asked the judge
to dismiss the case, saying that it has no merit.
“Unfortunately, the system is broken in this
case,” said Donald T. Netter, senior managing director at Dolphin
Financial Partners, a private investment partnership in Stamford, Conn.,
that is an infoUSA shareholder. “The board has failed to protect the
unaffiliated shareholders. When the system works properly, you shouldn’t
get into these situations.”
No kidding.
Many CEOs Receive Dividends on 'Phantom' Stock
Amid the drive to tie executive pay more closely to
company results, a little-known and poorly disclosed practice is allowing
many executives to receive hundreds of thousands of dollars a year in
dividends on performance stock -- shares that they may never earn . . .
Performance, or "phantom," shares are a form of restricted stock paid to an
executive only if the company meets certain performance targets. Dozens of
other CEOs are paid dividends on unvested restricted stock, which typically
requires the recipient only to wait several years before actually receiving
the shares, regardless of performance.
Scott Thurm, "Extra Pay: Many CEOs Receive Dividends on 'Phantom' Stock,"
The Wall Street Journal, May 4, 2006; Page A1 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB114671224745343502.html?mod=todays_us_nonsub_page_one
"Surprise! CEOs Are Still Highly Paid! "Deserve" has nothing to do
with it," by Holman W. Jenkins, The Wall Street Journal, May 03
2006 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB114661167480741940.html?mod=opinion&ojcontent=otep
It must be (insert time of day, season or year
here) because the air is filled with complaints about CEO pay. To wit,
CEOs are paid too much because they are "greedy." They are paid too much
because their wages are the product of a corrupt bargain with crony
boards. Sacred norms are violated: The average CEO makes 300 times an
average worker's salary. What is the "right" number and where does it
come from? The Bible? We'll get back to you.
You could do worse than revisit the case of one
Joseph Nacchio, former CEO of Qwest Communications, one of those
shamelessly overpaid CEOs of the '90s. It shows, in the end, that very
large CEO compensation is awarded in a logical and deliberate manner
because it serves the legitimate interests of those awarding it.
Mr. Nacchio, an executive at AT&T, was
recruited to Qwest by the company's founder, Denver billionaire Philip
Anschutz. Mr. Anschutz, a famously shrewd dealmaker, dangled an offer of
three million stock options, the explicit temptation being: Sign away
five years of your life and I will give you the chance to become
extraordinarily wealthy.
This is the basic transaction behind most
"outrageous" CEO pay. And Mr. Nacchio had the good sense to go where Mr.
Anschutz was leading him. Qwest's stock price soared and Mr. Nacchio
eventually exercised options for a pre-tax gain of $250 million.
Now we come to the reason for focusing on Mr.
Nacchio. In 2001, Mr. Anschutz prevailed on him to stay, offering
essentially the same deal over again, and Mr. Nacchio sat down with the
Rocky Mountain News to explain his compensation. What followed was a
rare exercise in realism about CEO pay.
He noted that several Qwest executives with
large stock-option windfalls had already left. "Look, it's very hard to
keep guys and gals who work in the normal corporate structure and then
all of a sudden over the period of two or three years, make $50 to $70
million. . . . Most people who make that kind of money will immediately
say: 'seen it, done it in the corporate world, I'm going to do something
else.'"
"I was faced with the choice: I either got to
leave at the end of five [years], or I have to stay for a substantive
period of time. . . . Look, I could go sit on the beach right now and
never have to do another day's work."
He added: "You might say if you want to stay,
why don't you just work for free? I think there are limits to how much
you want to do something. If I did that, then my investors would judge
my rationality and everything else I did."
There's a lot here, but suffice it to say, when
you hear Pfizer's board being criticized for having guaranteed Hank
McKinnell an $83 million retirement payout despite a crummy decade for
drug stocks, remember Mr. McKinnell is a rich man and could be on a
beach too.
Notice we don't use the language of "deserve"
or "worth" or "reward," common in complaints about CEO pay. These are
after-the-fact judgments, and any board that dishes up large pay for
performance that's already in the books isn't doing shareholders any
favor. "Pay for performance" is paying for the past, not the future,
which is what stock prices care about.
That's why CEO pay is about incentives -- the
incentive to commit to the job in the first place, the incentive to make
decisions that benefit shareholders. Should a company go for broke on a
new investment project or play it safe? Should it conserve cash or spend
lavishly on customer service and advertising? Should it pay bonuses to
employees or direct the same cash to the bottom line?
A shareholder is hardpressed to make these
calls from the sidelines. Meanwhile, tugging at a CEO's elbow all the
time are competing constituents who also want something at the company's
expense. Hence the use of stock options, unabated by controversy and
fully supported by valuations in the stock market, to put CEOs in the
place of owners when making these choices. In turn, the market sits in
judgment on a CEO's every move, adding or subtracting in a nanosecond a
sum from the company's market value that dwarfs even the CEO's pay
package.
You can complain, as critics do, that when
boards are giving away stock options or any company asset, they aren't
giving away something that belongs to them, so what do they care? Yep,
that's also true of the guy who fills the supply closet or authorizes a
new roof for the factory. It's true of the politicians who spend our tax
dollars and the charities that dispose of our donations. "Agency" is a
feature of organized life.
None of this means an Enron doesn't happen
occasionally. Very large sums dangled in front of people will make some
crazy (and we should note Mr. Nacchio is still fighting insider trading
charges related to his Qwest stock sales). But notice that the average
CEO, by the time he or she has spent a working life in one corporate job
after another, would not have succeeded without a finely tuned sense of
impulse control, a capacity to temper wishful thinking with realism, a
capacity for coolness and restraint in dealing with frustration,
opposition and risk.
What you get with the typical CEO, a few
exceptions notwithstanding, is a seasoned grown-up capable of acting
wisely and well under the heady incentives (and dangers) of corporate
life.
Rote disapproval has been a feature of the
landscape since pundits began noticing executive compensation 20 years
ago, but the critics should at least have the courage of their
resentment and stop trying to rationalize their disapproval with claims
that CEO pay isn't, by and large, an honest product of the marketplace.
High CEO pay exists because intelligent, savvy, self-interested
investors and their representatives believe it's in their interest to
award high CEO pay. And for that reason, high CEO pay won't be going
away.
Why linking pay to stock prices is liable to do more harm than good.
"Why Rules Can't Stop Executive Greed," by Daniel Akst, The New
York Times, March 5, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/03/05/business/yourmoney/05cont.html
In the arena of executive compensation, two
recent developments stand out against the backdrop of continuing
looting. First, the Securities and Exchange Commission announced plans
to make corporations more fully disclose executive pay. Second, a study
by Mercer Human Resource Consulting found that more companies were
imposing performance targets on the stock and options they granted to
C.E.O.'s.
To the uninitiated, these events may suggest
that some moderation is in the offing, but ultimately neither will help
much. Any benefit from shining the cleansing light of day on executive
greed will probably be outweighed by the inflationary effect of
additional disclosure, which will provide more ammunition for executives
and consultants seeking to justify additional increases. They have to
keep up with the Joneses, they'll say.
Tying pay more firmly to performance won't
help, either. Boards will find ways around the requirements if
performance isn't up to snuff, and they will continue to bid
irrationally for unduly coveted executives.
As Rakesh Khurana showed in his insightful
book, "Searching for a Corporate Savior: The Irrational Quest for
Charismatic C.E.O.'s" (Princeton University Press, 2002), there is a
much wider pool of potential chief executives than soaring pay levels
would seem to imply. But companies insist on bidding for a savior, not a
capable leader who knows the business at hand, which may be why typical
C.E.O. tenures are now so short. Even in the boardroom, charisma carries
you only so far.
Indeed, linking pay to stock prices is
liable to do more harm than good. A
stock price isn't much of a measure of executive performance, anyway. A
huge part of that price reflects industry conditions; energy companies
soared not because they were run by paragons of diligence or insight,
but because of world events beyond any executive's control. In hard
times, moreover, a company's stock may take a hit, but those are
precisely the times when good leadership is most difficult — and
valuable.
Other performance metrics can be equally
troublesome, encouraging executives to massage earnings, sacrifice
long-term strength for higher short-term sales and profits and otherwise
act in ways detrimental to everyone but the C.E.O., his family and a few
lucky divorce lawyers.
Perverse incentives notwithstanding, this focus
on metrics is a sad acknowledgment by corporate directors that they
cannot control themselves or the pay they hand over to their top five
executives. In one study, two professors, Lucian A. Bebchuk of Harvard
and Yaniv Grinstein of Cornell, found that from 2001 to 2003, such pay
totaled roughly 10 percent of corporate profits at public companies.
It's a bizarre twist on the tradition of tithing, one that benefits the
rich instead of the needy and conscripts America's shareholders as
involuntary donors.
Although more disclosure and
pay-for-performance requirements won't dampen runaway C.E.O.
compensation, both are useful for illustrating a larger lesson: that
it's naďve to place too much faith in the power of rules to limit human
behavior. Indeed, the problem of C.E.O. compensation suggests that, as
in many aspects of modern life, few mechanisms of constraint are as
effective as one on which we relied so often in the past. That mechanism
was shame.
You'd think that more disclosure would produce
more shame, and thus less pay, for C.E.O.'s and other top executives.
Unfortunately, disclosure of a few more million here and there won't
fundamentally change a hiring system that actively recruits the most
grasping and hubristic candidates. Consider the incentives: by offering
lavish pay and perks that would make royalty blush, corporate directors
today are perhaps unwittingly selecting C.E.O.'s for shamelessness and
egotism rather than leadership.
HISTORY teaches that there is no ultimate
solution to the so-called agency problem, or the tendency of those who
merely work in an enterprise to act in their own interest rather than
that of the owners. Rules and incentives can help, of course, but they
cannot take the place of an honest sense of obligation, duty and loyalty
— values that ought to run in all directions in any decent corporate
culture.
Continued in article
Seeing Fakes, Angry United Airline Employee-Shareholders Should be
Confronting the Bankruptcy Judge
The deal went through — with staggering
compensation to Wall Street — and in 1994 the American employees of UAL, as
a group, became its largest owners. Within a few years, overseas personnel
were allowed the privilege of tossing their life savings into UAL, too.
Trouble was not far behind. The employees found management demanding pay
cuts, big (and, for passengers, inconvenient) changes and cuts in scheduling
and services, and even silly changes in their once-great flight attendant
uniforms. Then came the blows of 9/11 and a recession, and then rising fuel
costs. There were demands for more cuts in pay and benefits and more
layoffs. That was not enough. About three years ago, UAL was "forced" to
enter bankruptcy to stay alive. This step meant that UAL could drastically
cut workers' pay — and it did. Pensions were simply jettisoned and made the
burden of the federal government's Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation,
which meant cuts of close to two-thirds in some pilots' pension payments.
And, of course, the bankruptcy simply eliminated all of that equity in UAL
that the employees had bought with their hard-earned savings.
Ben Stein, "When You Fly in First Class, It's Easy to Forget the Dots,"
The New York Times, January 29, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/01/29/business/yourmoney/29every.html
Here comes the good part: management has asked
the bankruptcy court to let it have — free — roughly 15 percent of the
stock in the new company, or about $900 million. Mr. Tilton, the chief
executive, who plays the Orson Welles character in this drama, would get
about $90 million personally for his hard work shepherding UAL through
bankruptcy (for which he was already paid multiple millions of dollars).
The bankruptcy court, instead of ordering Mr.
Tilton's arrest, instead cut the management share to about 8 percent, so
he will get more than $40 million, more or less. That is more than Lee
R. Raymond, the chief executive of Exxon Mobil, one of the most
successful companies of all time, was paid in 2004 (not counting Mr.
Raymond's 28 million shares of restricted stock).
So here it is in a nutshell: employees are
goaded into investing a big chunk of their wages and benefits in UAL
stock. They lose that. Then they lose big parts of their pay and
pensions. They become peons of UAL. Management gets $480 million, more
or less. "Creative destruction?" Or looting?
Wait, Mr. Tilton and Mr. Bankruptcy Judge. The
employees were the owners of UAL. They were the trustors, and Mr. Tilton
and his pals were trustees for them. How were the trustors wiped out
while the trustees, the fiduciaries, became fantastically rich? Is this
the way capitalism is supposed to work? Trustors save up, and their
agents just take their savings away from them?
If the company is worth so much that management
has hundreds of millions coming to them, shouldn't the employee-owners
get a taste? Does capitalism mean anything if the owners of the capital
can be wiped out while their agents grow wealthy? Is this a way to
encourage savings and the ownership society? Or is this a matter of to
him who hath shall be given?
I know that this is basically the same story I
described recently concerning the Delphi Corporation, where something
similar is going on. But that's exactly the point. Management is using
competition, higher fuel costs and every other cost complaint to cut the
pay and pensions of its own employees while enriching itself.
And I can well imagine what goes through Mr.
Tilton's mind as he does it: "Hey, I'm a great executive. Great
executives in private-equity firms make more than I do. Why shouldn't I
get the moolah? Basically, I've worked it so UAL is now a private-equity
deal anyway. That's what it's all about now, isn't it? Who's got the
most at the end of the day at Bighorn or the Reserve or whatever golf
course I choose to retire at? And, anyway, wouldn't you take $48 million
for a few of those dots we used to call our employees and owners to stop
moving?"
From The Wall Street Journal Accounting Weekly Review on January 13, 2006
TITLE: SEC to propose overhaul of Rules on Executive Pay
REPORTER: Kara Scannell
DATE: Jan 10, 2006
PAGE: A1
LINK:
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB113686357913042428.html
TOPICS: Accounting, Disclosure, Disclosure Requirements, Executive
compensation, Securities and Exchange Commission
SUMMARY: "The Securities and Exchange Commission, responding to rising
criticism of soaring--and partially hidden--executive pay, is poised to
propose the most sweeping overhaul of pay disclosure rules in 14 years,
seeking to push companies to divulge much more about their top executives'
perquisites, retirement benefits and total compensation.'
QUESTIONS:
1.) According to the description in the article, what are the problems and
issues associated with current disclosure requirements for executive
compensation? Where are those disclosures made? What entity establishes the
requirements for those disclosures?
2.) What benefit will come from placing "the monetary value of
stock-option grants...side by side with salary and bonus information"? How
are those "monetary values" of stock option grants determined?
3.) The article refers to a new FASB accounting standard related to stock
options. Summarize the requirements of that new standard. Will the changes
described in this article impact those requirements? Explain.
4.) Is the SEC hoping to curb executive compensation with this new
proposal? Explain your answer: if yes, indicate how disclosure might play a
role in this process; if no, indicate how this disclosure change is
independent of any desire to curb compensation.
5.) Shering-Plough's chief executive, Fred Hassan, stated that his
company's managements believes that "transparency is good for
shareholders...particularly if additional disclosures allow shareholders to
look at the compensation in the context of management's performance..."
Describe one way in which you might undertake an analysis from an investor's
point of view to use disclosures about executive compensation in this way.
SMALL GROUP ASSIGNMENT: Assign group members to access corporate
financial statements and proxy filings by industry, by student choice of
company of interest, or any other method of choosing. Access the SEC's web
site to obtain electronic access to both the most recent quarterly filing
and the proxy statement. Ask students to describe the information found in
these corporate filings and explain where they find the information. Make
comparisons by company or across industry lines in amounts and types of
executive compensation.
Access filings on the SEC web using the following steps described for
Google, Inc.:
Access www.sec.gov
Click on Search for Company Filings Under General-Purpose Searches, click on
Companies & Other Filers In the box for Company name, type Google and click
"Find companies" Click on the third CIK, 0001288776 In the box for Form
Type, type DEF 14A (for proxy statements) and 10-Q (for quarterly reports)
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University of Rhode Island
Correcting this CEO IPO fraud is long overdue
"A Major Perk For Executives Takes a Big Hit: McLeod Ruling Makes
It Tougher To Accept Lucrative IPO Shares; Broader Definition of
'Spinning'," by Michael Siconolfi, The Wall Street Journal, February
21, 2006; Page C1 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB114048274500878570.html?mod=todays_europe_money_and_investing
Corporate executives, take note: The definition
of improper stock trading in your brokerage account just got broader.
A New York state court recently found former
telecommunications executive Clark E. McLeod liable for receiving hot
new stocks in his personal brokerage account. The rationale: His company
was sending business to the same securities firm, Citigroup Inc.'s
Salomon Smith Barney, that doled him the new stocks.
That is a big change. Previously, "spinning" of
initial public offerings of stock involved a direct quid pro quo. In a
common form, securities firms allocated IPOs to the personal accounts of
corporate executives, so the shares could then be sold, or "spun," for
quick profits -- in exchange for business from the executives'
companies.
IPO shares are coveted because they often surge
on their first trading day. Spinning has raised concerns among investors
that the IPO market is rigged.
Bottom line: Senior executives now could skate
on thin legal ice if they receive IPO shares from a Wall Street firm
with which their company at some point does business, and don't disclose
it to their board or shareholders.
The ruling has broader ramifications. Even
though Mr. McLeod lived and worked in Cedar Rapids, Iowa, the judge said
the New York attorney general could bring the case because the
transactions were made through a New York firm. Most securities firms do
business in New York.
This is an "expansive interpretation" of
corporate executives' duty, says Joseph Grundfest, a former commissioner
at the Securities and Exchange Commission and now a law and business
professor at Stanford University.
The ruling comes as the IPO market heats up
again. So far this year, there have been 32 new stock issues brought to
market, raising $5.8 billion; the average first-day gain has been 11%,
according to Richard Peterson, a senior researcher at Thomson Financial,
a New York financial-data provider.
Mr. McLeod, 59 years old, declined to comment.
He will appeal the "completely novel" ruling, says one of his lawyers,
Richard Werder, a partner at Jones Day.
A former mathematics and science teacher, Mr.
McLeod started a long-distance company out of his garage in 1980. He
eventually founded McLeod Inc., a telecom upstart now known as McLeodUSA
Inc. that fell victim to the bursting of the technology-stock bubble. He
left as chief executive in April 2002; McLeodUSA emerged from
bankruptcy-law protection last month. He currently is CEO of
Fiberutilities of Iowa, a utility-management company.
Continued in article
Bob Jensen's threads on security frauds are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudRotten.htm
Bob Jensen's updates on fraud are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudUpdates.htm
Figuring execs' pay hard, even for pros (like Denny Beresford)
The question seems simple enough: What did
Coca-Cola pay its chief executive, Neville Isdell, for his first year at the
helm? Dennis Beresford is trying to come up with the answer as he digs into
a disclosure report Coke released last year. Surely he's up to the task,
being an accounting professor at the University of Georgia, chairman of
audit committees at two major companies, and a former chairman of the
Financial Accounting Standards Board. He takes nearly 20 minutes. But his
answer --- "in the general area of $17 million"--- could be off by as much
as $14 million. Seems Beresford missed a small footnote in the documents and
didn't accurately assess the value of some stock options.
Matt Kempner, "Figuring execs' pay hard, even for pros," Atlanta
Journal-Constitution, January 21, 2006 ---
http://www.ajc.com/
A
look at the proxy's "Summary Compensation Table" didn't give Beresford
all the information he was looking for. He added up the dollar figures
there and came up with nearly $11 million for Isdell. Then the professor
scoured footnotes and other tables and decided to include an additional
$6 million or so, representing about 450,000 stock options.
That brought the total for Isdell to roughly $17 million.
But as Beresford tried to complete the task quickly, he missed a
footnote mentioning about 621,000 additional stock options. The options
were awarded in early 2005 and based on Isdell's performance in 2004.
"I was obviously not looking at every footnote as I went through, which
I should have," Beresford said later. The additional options could have
been worth an additional $8 million or so.
Oops. Then came another issue. While Beresford saw an award of
"Performance Share Units," they were based on Coke share prices that he
didn't know off the top of his head. He didn't factor the units into the
total, which could add an additional $5 million to $6 million.
If all the extras were included, it could bump Isdell's total package
from $17 million to about $31 million. And that doesn't include Isdell's
potential pension benefits, which Beresford struggled to quickly
tabulate since he couldn't find all the information he needed in the
proxy.
James Reda, a New York-based compensation consultant for corporate
boards, said he isn't surprised that a sharp investor could be way off
trying to total up executive pay.
Smaller companies --- generally those with less than $200 million in
revenue --- usually have pay deals that are easier to dissect. But with
a large company, Reda said, his staffers spend more than three hours
trying to come up with total compensation as well as payouts due when a
CEO leaves.
"Companies don't try to make it easy," he said.
Even with the disclosure changes mandated by the SEC, Beresford
questioned how much easier it will be for investors to come up with a
realistic total of executive compensation. Pay packages are complex and
can depend on a number of future variables.
Said Beresford: "I suspect the simplified approach is going to be a very
long document."
At Coke, the company plans to review the SEC's proposed changes, Sutlive
said. "We fully support transparency and clarity in corporate financial
reporting, including executive compensation."
To the company's credit, it disclosed some of the stock options and
Performance Share Units awarded to Isdell even though it says it wasn't
required to for another year.
And
what does Coke calculate Isdell's 2004 compensation package to be?
Somewhere between $10.9 million and $17.5 million, depending on how you
value the options.
Continued in article
Gee, why hadn't I thought of that?! This is a cool one!
"a vast academic literature has emerged on
executive compensation. A predominant focus of this literature has been
equity-based compensation, paid in the form of restricted stock, stock
options, and other instruments whose value is tied to future equity returns"
"Overlooked almost entirely is the widespread
practice of paying top managers with debt."
From Jim Mahar's blog on January 20, 2006 ---
http://financeprofessorblog.blogspot.com/
Gee, why hadn't I thought of that?! This is
a cool one!
SSRN-Pay Me Later: Inside Debt and its Role in
Managerial Compensation by Rangarajan Sundaram, David Yermack: "CEOs
with high debt-based incentives manage their firms conservatively to
reduce default risk; and that pension plan compensation strongly
influences patterns of CEO turnover and CEO cash compensation."
The authors make an important contribution by
pointing out the obvious: namely that CEOs get pain in ways other than
cash and equity. This is a fact that has largely been overlooked by
researchers (at least partially due to data availability). From the
paper:
"a vast academic literature has emerged on
executive compensation. A predominant focus of this literature has been
equity-based compensation, paid in the form of restricted stock, stock
options, and other instruments whose value is tied to future equity
returns"
"Overlooked almost entirely is the widespread
practice of paying top managers with debt."
CEO pay is rarely in the form of traditional
market-based debt but several forms of pay (specifically pensions and
long term deferred compensation contracts) have the same characteristics
as debt. In Jensen and Meckling terms this 'inside debt" is hypothesized
to affect the incentives of the CEOs.
After a case study showing how deferred
compenstaion and pension benefits were important in the Jack Welch/GE
world, the authors show that this "inside debt" does make up a large
portion of CEO pay and that this is more important as CEOs near
retirement.
Using large firms (237 forms from teh Fortune
500 of 2002) the authors report the expected; debt does change behavior
with managers becoming more risk averse. (Rememeber if we assume
managers are people and people respond to changes in incentives, then
managers respond to incentives. So while important, the findings should
not be seen as surprising.)
"As CEO pension values increase relative to
their equity values, risk-taking as measured by distance-to default
declines."
Good (and important) stuff! I^3!!!
Cite: Sundaram, Rangarajan K. and Yermack, David, "Pay Me Later:
Inside Debt and its Role in Managerial Compensation" (May 16, 2005).
NYU, Law and Economics Research Paper No. 05-08; AFA 2006 Boston
Meetings Paper.
http://ssrn.com/abstract=717102
January 23, 2006 reply from Dennis Beresford
[dberesfo@TERRY.UGA.EDU]
Bob,
No I didn't. I think the point is that
compensation consultants and others will try to work around whatever the
SEC finally requires in this area. That's just human nature and what
they get paid to do!
Denny
Coke Decides Enough is Enough
Under pressure from one of its big shareholders, Coke adopted a new policy
requiring that its stockholders approve certain executive severance
agreements.
Gretchen Morgenson, Severance Pay Doesn't Go Better With Coke," The New
York Times, December 25, 2005 ---
http://snipurl.com/CokeSeverancePay
Executive Compensation: Here's how it works even in bankruptcy
Last Wednesday, the judge overseeing the UAL
Corporation's reorganization approved an executive pay package that would
give rich salaries and at least $115 million worth of stock to the airline
company's chief executive, Glenn F. Tilton, and other senior managers, when
UAL emerges from Chapter 11. UAL said the executive pay was necessary to
attract and retain experienced managers. But the judge's approval surprised
Brian Foley, an executive pay expert in White Plains. For starters, he
noted, the plan was created by Towers Perrin for the UAL board. Towers
Perrin also happens to have done work for UAL management.
"A Little Too Close for Comfort at UAL?" The New York Times, January
22, 2006 ---
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/01/22/business/yourmoney/22suits.html
Jensen Comment
All the pilots, flight attendants, machinists, ticket agents, baggage
handlers, and other UAL employees took pay cuts. Why not the top
brass? Just goes to show you that there's no economic law of supply and
demand at the CEO level. It's all a matter of back scratching where the CEO
appoints the Board that in turn decide how much the CEO can loot from
shareholders.
I don't know whether to post this to my "White Collar Crime" module or my
"Outrageous Executive Compensation" module. These days both modules
should probably be merged.
Did Enron change executive looting tendencies?
Despite an array of new and expensive laws and
regulations that were adopted to tighten corporate oversight after the wave
of scandals earlier in the decade, serious accounting problems continue to
trouble publicly owned companies. In the last year, a record number have
been forced to correct erroneous earnings statements, which often led to
sharp stock declines. Moreover, for all the widespread criticism of high pay
of executives at Enron and other companies that later proved derelict,
studies show that there is still little overall correlation between the
performance of many companies and the executive compensation set by their
directors.
Stepen Labaton, "Four Years Later, Enron's Shadow Lingers as Change Comes
Slowly," The New York Times, January 5, 2005 ---
http://snipurl.com/NYT0105
Dance with
the one who brought (bought?) you!
Financial performance reporting transparency or in this case lack
thereof in accounting
A growing number of companies are paying extra sums to cover executives'
personal tax bills, even as CEO compensation continues to soar. Details of
the "tax gross-ups" are often buried in impenetrable footnotes or obscure
filings.
"Latest Twist in Corporate Pay: Tax-Free Income for Executives," by Mark
Maremont, The Wall Street Journal, December 22, 2005 ---
http://online.wsj.com/article/SB113521937434129170.html?mod=todays_us_page_one
Amid soaring CEO compensation, a number of
companies are paying extra sums to cover executives' personal tax bills.
Many companies are paying taxes due on core elements of executive pay,
such as stock grants, signing bonuses and severance packages. Others are
reimbursing taxes on corporate perquisites, which are treated as income
by the Internal Revenue Service. They run the gamut from personal travel
aboard corporate jets to country-club memberships and shopping
excursions.
"This
smacks of Leona Helmsley-like treatment, that only little people
pay taxes," says Patrick McGurn, an executive vice president of
Institutional Shareholder Services Inc., an influential adviser
to big investors that often critiques companies'
corporate-governance practices. For these top executives, he
says, companies "are removing taxes from the list of inevitable
life experiences, leaving only death."
Details of the little-known payments,
called "tax gross-ups," are often buried in impenetrable
footnotes or obscure filings. In its 2005 proxy statement, Home
Depot didn't disclose many of the perks it must give Mr.
Nardelli, or that the company is required to reimburse him for
taxes related to those perks. The company provided specifics of
these benefits and the gross-ups in his employment agreement,
which was attached to a 2001 regulatory filing. (Read
Home Depot's filing.)
Continued
in article |
The question is: Why don't the auditors insist on transparent
disclosures?
Coke Decides Enough is Enough
Under pressure from one of its big shareholders, Coke adopted a new policy
requiring that its stockholders approve certain executive severance
agreements.
Gretchen Morgenson, Severance Pay Doesn't Go Better With Coke," The New
York Times, December 25, 2005 ---
http://snipurl.com/CokeSeverancePay
COMPANY DIRECTORS - WHOM DO THEY
SERVE? --- http://www.ragm.com/archpub/ragm/company_directors.html
“Dance with
the one who brought you”
“So long as
owners remained in charge and hired managers to help run the business,
salaries were ample but not extravagant. J.P. Morgan, for example, made
it a point never to pay an executive more than twenty times the earnings
of the lowliest employee in the organization. As late as 1900, salaries
of $5,000 -$6,000 (or $80,000 - $95,000 in today’s currency) were not
uncommon for presidents of substantial manufacturing companies, and the
average compensation for top managers of large firms prior to World War
I was slightly below $10,000. - less than the pay of a university
president. Not until owners relinquished power, and managers were
accountable only to thousands of shareholders, was the way clear to
granting emoluments on the lavish scale we know today.”
It is a part of
the worldwide definition of the corporation that the shareholders elect
the members of the board of directors and that the directors will be
responsible for the conduct of the business, including the selection of
executive officers. And yet in reality shareholders do not elect the
directors and directors are not responsible for the conduct of the
business, and this gulf between myth and reality seems acceptable, even
preferred. Shareholders do not elect directors; the Chief Executive
Officer selects the board members; they are routinely “nominated” by
a committee comprised of incumbent directors; theirs are the only names
that appear on the company proxy which is distributed at corporate
expense to all shareholders; management counts the votes and calls those
who cast a vote against to try to persuade them to change their minds,
and it is virtually impossible for anyone other than management to get a
name on the company proxy, so challengers must bear all the expenses of
providing alternate candidates while the management slate uses corporate
funds. The result is that the “election” of the management slate is
as safely guaranteed as that of the Chief Executive of Albania during
the half century following World War II.
Continued at http://www.ragm.com/archpub/ragm/company_directors.html
"Salary Is the Least of It," Fortune, April 28, 2003, Page
59
While shocking in one sense, these
developments are not wholly surprising. For several decades now, CEO
pay has been governed by the Law of Unintended Compensation, which holds
that any attempt to reduce compensation has the perverse result of
increasing it.
- In 1989, Congress tries to cap golden
parachutes by imposing an excise tax on payments above 2.99 times base
salary. Result: Companies make 2.99 the new minimum and cover any
excise tax for execs.
- In 1992, Congress tries to shame CEOs
by requiring better disclosure of their pay. Result: CEOs see how
much everyone else is making, and then try to get more.
- In 1993, Congress declares salaries
over $1 million to be non-tax-exempt. Result: Companies opt for
huge stock option grants while upping most salaries to $1 million.
You get the idea. Regulation is a
spur to innovation, and in the pay arena innovation always means
"more." As executive-pay critic Graef Crystal once put it,
"The more troughs a pig feeds from, the fatter it gets."
"CEO PAY: Have They No Shame?" by Jerry Useem, Fortune, April 14,
2003 --- http://www.fortune.com/fortune/ceo/articles/0,15114,443051,00.html
CEO performance stank last year, yet most CEOs got paid more than ever.
Here's how they're getting away with it.
But the pigs were so clever that they could
think of a way round every difficulty.
--George Orwell, Animal Farm
Who says CEOs don't suffer along with the rest of
us? As his company's stock slid 71% last year, one corporate chief saw his
compensation fall 12%. Sure, he still earned $82 million, making him the
second-highest-paid executive at an S&P 500 company in 2002, according
to the 360 proxy statements that had rolled in as of April 9. And yeah, he's
under indictment for the wholesale looting of his company, Tyco. But at
least Dennis Kozlowski set a better example than the top-paid executive, who
pulled in a whopping $136 million. That was Mark Swartz, his former CFO.
Unusual, you might say, for one company to produce
the two top earners in a given year. But three of the top six? Now that's
truly striking--especially since the other person isn't part of Kozlowski's
gang at all. It's Ed Breen, the guy hired to clean up the mess.
You'd think that in the aftermath of a scandal that
made Tyco a symbol of cartoonish greed, its board might want to make a point
of frugality. Yet even as it was pressuring its former officers to
"disgorge" their ill-gotten gains, it was letting its new man, who
became CEO last July, gorge himself on $62 million worth of cash, stock, and
other prizes. By all accounts Breen is doing a fine job so far (see Exorcism
at Tyco), but still. And the gravy train didn't stop there. Tyco's board
of directors dished out another $25 million for a new CFO, plus $25 million
to a division head, putting them both on a par with the CEOs of Wal-Mart and
General Electric. At least the company, now with a new board of directors,
seems to recognize the need for some limits: Its bonus scheme "now caps
out at 200% of base salary," notes Breen, "whereas before it was
more like 600% or 700%."
That, in a nutshell, is what a year of
unprecedented uproar and outrage can do. Before, CEOs had a shot at becoming
very, very, very rich. Now they're likely to get only very, very rich. More
likely, in fact. FORTUNE asked Equilar, an independent provider of
compensation data, to analyze CEO compensation at 100 of the largest
companies that had filed proxy statements for 2002. Their findings? Average
CEO compensation dropped 23% in 2002, to $15.7 million, but that's mostly
because the pay of a few mega-earners fell significantly. A more telling
number--median compensation, or what the middle-of-the-road CEO
earned--actually rose 14%, to $13.2 million. This in a year when the total
return of the S&P 500 was down 22.1%.
"The acid test for reform," wrote Warren
Buffett in his most recent letter to shareholders, "will be CEO
compensation." With most of the results now in, the acid strip is
bright red: Corporate reform has failed. Not only does executive pay seem
more decoupled from performance than ever, but boards are conveniently
changing their definition of "performance." "From a
compensation point of view," says Matt Ward, an independent pay
consultant, "it's a whole new bag of tricks."
What did fall last year were monster grants of
stock options, like the 20 million awarded to Apple's Steve Jobs in 2000.
The declining use of options (which even Kozlowski once called a "free
ride--a way to earn megabucks in a bull market") would seem cause for
reformers to rejoice. But delve more closely into the data for those 100 big
companies and what do you find? That every other form of
compensation--including some burgeoning forms of stealth wealth--has grown.
Continued in the article.
Also see Enron's Cast of Characters at http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/FraudEnronCast.htm
From The Wall Street Journal
Accounting Educators' Reviews, October 27, 2003
TITLE: Everything You Wanted to Know
About Corporate Governance . . .
REPORTER: Judith Burns
DATE: Oct 27, 2003
PAGE: R5-6
LINK: http://online.wsj.com/article_print/0,,SB106676280248746100,00.html
TOPICS: Corporate Governance, Internal Auditing, Sarbanes-Oxley Act,
Securities and Exchange Commission, Audit Committee
SUMMARY: A special section on
corporate governance in the Oct. 27 WSJ addresses the issue of corporate
governance in some detail. Included is the article by Judith Burns with a
primer on what corporate governance is and relating it to the parties
involved. Several related articles recount why this is a topical issue and
what are the prospects in the future, including the Hymowitz article detailing
the duties of a corporate board member.
QUESTIONS:
1.) Define corporate governance. Does it ensure superior firm performance? Why
is it important to investors? Who are the major parties involved in this
issue? Briefly discuss the roles each plays in it.
2.) What are the responsibilities of:
the Board of Directors; the Chief Executive Officer; the internal auditors;
the external auditors; the Compensation Committee; the Nominating Committee;
the Auditing Committee; and the SEC? Where they apparently exist, explain
potential conflicts of interest and how this "muddies the waters"
where the responsibilities are concerned.
3.) What effects have this issue had
on credit-rating agencies and insurance companies?
4.) Does the CEO hire the Board of
Directors? Why or why not? In the Maremont and Bandler article, who failed in
the governance of Tyco?
5.) How has the Sarbanes-Oxley Act
affected these relationships? Have they had unintended consequences? On
balance, has the Act met its intended purposes? Are more legislative changes
anticipated?
Reviewed By: Judy Beckman, University
of Rhode Island
Reviewed By: Benson Wier, Virginia Commonwealth University
Reviewed By: Kimberly Dunn, Florida Atlantic University
--- RELATED ARTICLES IN THE WALL
STREET JOURNAL ---
TITLE: How to Be a Good Director
REPORTER: Carol Hymowitz
PAGE: R1-4
ISSUE: Sep 27, 2002
LINK: http://online.wsj.com/article_print/0,,SB10667541869215200,00.html
TITLE: Now Playing: Corporate
America's Funniest Home Video
REPORTER: Mark Maremont and James Bandler
PAGE: A1-8
ISSUE: Oct 29, 2003
LINK: http://online.wsj.com/article_print/0,,SB106735726682798800,00.html
(See the Yawn below)
Yawn!
Corporate America's Funniest (read that most boring) Home Video
The Wall Street Journal, October 29, 2003
20-minute video of an extravagant birthday party for the wife of former Tyco
CEO L. Dennis Kozlowski depicts what many consider the height of corporate
excess. Three videos can be downloaded from links below:
Excerpt;
http://play.rbn.com/?dowjones/wsj/demand/wsj_vid/tyco1_hi.rm
Full:
Part
1: http://play.rbn.com/?dowjones/wsj/demand/wsj_vid/tyco2_hi.rm
Full:
Part
2): http://play.rbn.com/?dowjones/wsj/demand/wsj_vid/tyco3_hi.rm
This is a Roman Orgy without the orgy. Actually everybody looks pretty
boring and bored. Neither video shows the life-sized naked woman
birthday cake. And the sculpture of David peeing vodka was edited out of
the flicks. The cake and the sculpture were not shown to the jury in the
Kozlowski trial. Just why these were edited out is a mystery to me since
they depict the sickness of this former Tyco CEO more than the tame stuff on
the jury's videos where all the bored actors in togas wore underwear.
What's left on the tape isn't worth watching except to witness a boring waste
of $2 million in corporate dough. I've attended funeral parties (e.g.,
for my friend John Bacon) in Pilots Grill in Bangor, Maine where the guests
had more fun.
Bottom Line Conclusion: Success of a corporate party is defined as what
it cost rather than what it bought.
Has anybody read whether any partners
from PwC attended the birthday bash?
An enormous mystery for the Manhattan
prosecutors has been how much Tyco’s auditors knew about the about allegedly
improper bonuses paid to Kozlowski and other executives along with the
improper spending of corporate funds for personal expenses such as
Kozlowski’s $65,000 New England golf club membership --- http://www.yourlawyer.com/practice/printnews.htm?story_id=2104
October 29, 2003 reply from Patricia Doherty [pdoherty@BU.EDU]
-----Original Message-----
From: Patricia Doherty [mailto:pdoherty@BU.EDU]
Sent: Wednesday, October 29, 2003 9:20 AM
Subject: Re: Corporate America's Most Boring Home Video
I suppose one interesting fact that emerged is the
fact that his mistress planned his wife’s birthday party. Remarkable what
some people will put up with for money. They deserve each other.
"If not this, then what?
If not now, then when?
If not you, then who?"
Patricia A. Doherty
Instructor in Accounting
Coordinator, Managerial Accounting
Boston University School of Management
595 Commonwealth Avenue
Boston, MA 02215
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate fraud --- http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/fraud.htm
"Corporate Governance and
Equity Prices," by Paul A. Gompers, et al. July 2002 --- http://icf.som.yale.edu/Conference-Papers/Fall2001/gov.pdf
Note that this paper has a great Glossary of terms.
The power-sharing
relationship between investors and managers is defined by the rules of
corporate governance. In the United States, these rules are given in
corporate legal documents and in state and federal laws. There is
significant variation in these rules across different firms, resulting in
large differences in the balance of power between investors and managers.
Using a sample of about 1,500 firms per year and 24 corporate-governance
provisions during the 1990s, we build a Governance Index, denoted as “G”,
to proxy for the balance of power between managers and shareholders in each
firm. We then analyze the empirical relationship of this index to stock
returns, firm value, operating measures, capital expenditure, and
acquisition activity.
We find that
corporate governance is strongly correlated with stock returns during the
1990s: an investment strategy that purchased shares in the firms with the
lowest G (strongest shareholder rights), and sold short firms with the
highest G (weakest shareholder rights), earned abnormal returns of 8.5
percent per year. At the beginning of the sample, there is already a
significant relationship between valuation and governance: each one-point
increase in G is associated with a 2.4 percentage point lower value for
Tobin’s Q. By the end of the decade, this difference has increased
significantly, with a one-point increase in G associated with an 8.9
percentage point lower value for Tobin’s Q.
Continued at http://icf.som.yale.edu/Conference-Papers/Fall2001/gov.pdf
"System Failure:
Corporate America: We Have a Crisis," Fortune Magazine
Cover Story, June 24, 2002 --- http://www.fortune.com/indexw.jhtml?channel=artcol.jhtml&doc_id=208314
Pay CEOs,
Yeah--But Not So Much Before they stumbled, they cashed in. Enron's Jeff
Skilling made $112 million off his stock options in the three years
before his company collapsed. Tyco's Dennis Kozlowski cashed in $240
million over three years before he got the boot. Joe Nacchio, who's
still in charge at Qwest but has left investors billions poorer, made
$232 million off options in three years.
If you're
looking for reasons corporate America is in such ill repute, this kind
of over-the-top CEO piggishness is a big one. Investors and in some
cases employees lost everything, while the architects of their pain
laughed all the way to the bank.
The funny thing
is, we asked for it. "Pay for performance" was what investors
wanted--and to a significant extent, got: For the first time in memory,
CEOs' cash compensation actually dropped in 2001, by 2.8%, according to
Mercer Human Resource Consulting. The value of top executives' stock and
options holdings in many cases dropped by a lot more than that.
But while CEO
pay has become more variable--and study after study has shown it to be
more closely linked to company performance than it used to be--it has
also grown unspeakably generous. Fifteen years ago the highest-paid CEO
in the land was Chrysler's Lee Iacocca, who took home $20 million. Last
year's No. 1, Larry Ellison of Oracle, made $706 million.
There are a lot
of complicated, difficult-to-change reasons for this. Some are addressed
in the next item, on corporate governance (see also "The Great CEO
Pay Heist" in fortune.com). Some may be insoluble. In any case,
we're probably due an acrimonious national debate over just what a CEO
is worth. But for now, here's a straightforward suggestion: Force
companies to stop pretending that the stock options they give their
executives are free.
It's probably
safe to say that Oracle's board would never have paid Larry Ellison $706
million in cash or any other form that would have to show up on the
company's earnings statement. All that money (Ellison didn't get a
salary last year) came from exercising stock options that the company
had given him in earlier years. And because of the current screwed-up
accounting for stock options, Oracle's earnings statement says that
Ellison's bonanza didn't cost the company a cent.
Options are by
far the biggest component of CEO pay these days. Virtually all of the
most eye-popping CEO bonanzas have come from options exercises. While it
is sometimes argued that options are popular because they link the
interests of executives with those of shareholders, there are other,
possibly better ways to do that--outright grants of stock, for
instance--that don't get used nearly as much as options because they
have to be expensed.
Do the markets
really have trouble seeing through this kind of financial gimmickry? Are
boards really so influenced by an accounting loophole? In a word, yes.
"Anybody who fights the reported-earnings obsession does so at
their own peril," says compensation guru Ira Kay of the consulting
firm Watson Wyatt. So let's make companies charge the estimated value of
the options they give out against their earnings, and see if the options
hogs are up to the fight.
The past six months have featured
a parade of corporate leaders who were irresponsible stewards of other
people's money and trust. They were apparently so consumed by greed that
they never dreamed of getting caught, ruining companies, and shaming
themselves. In so doing, they have created what Al Vicere, a professor of
strategic leadership at Pennsylvania State University's Smeal College of
Business, calls a CEO "credibility crisis." All of which raises
the question: Why? What is it about the character of today's corporate
chieftains that has led them into CEO-gate -- which at times prompts them
to indulge in behavior more reminiscent of fallen TV ministers than of
upstanding community leaders?
FULL VERSION http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/jun2002/nf20020613_9296.htm?c=bwcareersjun26&n=link1&t=email
One of the best sites that I have encountered regarding news and issues in
corporate governance is maintained by Robert Monks at http://www.ragm.com/index.asp
The site should also be of great interest to those interested in ethics,
environmental, and social responsibility. Robert Monks is a veteran
director of over a dozen large corporations. At best he is only cautiously
optimistic about reforms that might emerge from the current scandals like Enron,
WorldCom, and Andersen. He most certainly thinks that members of the audit
committees and boards of directors are ineffective in controlling corporate
graft, because they do not have access to company resources needed for such a
task Robert Monks is featured on Page 35 of the June 2002
issue of Financial Executive --- http://www.fei.org/magazine/May2002.cfm
The Biggest Crime of
All: They Still Don't Get It
"Wall
Streets CEOs Still Get Fat Paychecks Despite Woes," by Susanne Craig, The
Wall Street Journal, March 3, 2003
Chiefs'
Packages Decline Overall Still, $10 Million or More Isn't Bad
Stock
markets are down. Corporate public offerings are out. Investors are on the
sidelines. And financial firms continue to cut staff.
But
there is still a bull market in one pocket of Wall Street -- the pay of
securities-firm CEOs.
Amid
one of the worst operating environments in years, Wall Street chief
executives continue to pull down annual paychecks topping $10 million. Even
though their pay is down overall, it is still turning heads in many
quarters. Morgan Stanley's CEO Philip Purcell received a 2002 pay
package of $11 million. Goldman Sachs Group Inc.'s Henry Paulson made
$12.1 million and Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc.'s Richard Fuld took
home a pay package valued at $12.5 million.
Citigroup
Inc.'s Chief Executive Sanford I. Weill, whose banking firm has been dogged
by regulatory probes this year, volunteered not to receive a cash or stock
bonus for 2002 because the share price of the company, which owns Salomon
Smith Barney, dropped 25% during the year.
But
Citigroup's board granted Mr. Weill stock options for 2003 with an current
estimated value of $17.9 million, more than the $17 million cash bonus Mr.
Weill received in 2001. At Bear Stearns Cos., one of the few
securities firms that actually saw its profit rise in 2002, CEO James Cayne
saw his total compensation more than double to $19.6 million last year.
The
still-hefty paychecks are drawing criticism as being out of whack with these
tough economic times. On Wall Street, fees from the most profitable
businesses -- such merger-and-acquisition advice and underwriting initial
public offerings of stock -- have all but dried up.
"The
problem is there is no strong indication the bear market is over and we are
a long way from justifying these type of packages," says Mike
Corasaniti, director of research at boutique investment firm Keefe, Bruyette
& Woods Inc. and an adjunct professor in the business department
of Columbia University in New York .
"In
good times boards justify the big pay packages by saying the executives are
doing a great job and in bad times they justify the pay by saying they are
managing in a difficult environment. No matter what, they seem to find a way
to rationalize it."
Officials
at the various firms declined to comment
Of
course, a Wall Street CEO's pay is tied to performance. And the job hasn't
been easy. But the tough decision to cut staff may have in fact boosted the
pay packages of many top executives, as the cost-cutting measures kicked in.
With the exception of a few firms, notably Credit Suisse Group's
Credit Suisse First Boston, most Wall Street firms have actually been making
money during the bear market. CSFB reported a loss for 2002 of $811 million,
due to $813 million in charges to cover items ranging from 1,500 previously
announced job cuts to a provision for civil-litigation costs.
Also
see http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/fraudVirginia.htm
Additional Reading
The New Robber Barons --- http://www.labornet.org/viewpoints/workman.html
Derek C. Bok, The Cost of Talent How Executives and Professionals are
Paid and How It Affects America (Free Press 1993)
Peter Drucker, The Bored Board, in Toward the Next Economics and Other
Essays, Harper & Roe, New York, 1981
Bob Jensen's threads on corporate governance are at
http://faculty.trinity.edu/rjensen/Fraud001.htm#Governance
|